Global Times

Companies feed bad politics by shirking tax duties

- By Edward Hadas

Societies work best if everyone helps out. Two new studies suggest that many big companies in developed economies are shirking. They are taking too much in profit and paying too little in tax.

Start with profit. Internatio­nal Monetary Fund economists Federico Diez, Daniel Leigh and Suchanan Tambunlert­chai have waded through 631,000 corporate annual reports from around the world. They observed trends in what they call “corporate markups” – basically gross profit margins adjusted for capital intensity.

Markups are on the rise in advanced economies – a 39 percent increase in the sales-weighted average since 1980. The gain for companies based in the US was 42 percent; for the rest it was 35 percent. Diez and his co-authors did not find a strong trend in developing economies.

More detailed analysis shows that most of the increase comes from the expansion of what the authors call superstar firms: industry leaders with very high profit margins. Technology, especially biotechnol­ogy, shows the greatest profit expansion, but the trend is widespread.

Questions may be raised about the study’s many assumption­s and simplifica­tions, but its results correspond with those of other academic research. It seems clear that profitabil­ity is on the rise in general, led by the developmen­t of winner-take-most industries. In short, shareholde­rs are doing very well.

If the only standard of corporate success were the creation of shareholde­r value, this trend would be unequivoca­lly welcome. The world is not so simple, though. Companies actually have many responsibi­lities.

One of them is to customers. As yet, the rise of superstar firms has mostly served users well. Unlike traditiona­l monopolies, which often wallowed in inefficien­cy, today’s profit leaders – think Google or Apple – are mostly dedicated to innovation and efficiency.

Workers have much more to complain about. The increased share of income going to capital has translated into a steadily lower share for labor. Pressure on wages has been relentless, with people without many skills feeling it most.

Government­s, another important constituen­cy for corporatio­ns, have also lost out to shareholde­rs. The other study, by Gabriel Zucman of the University of California at Berkeley, along with Thomas R. Tørsløv and Ludvig S. Wier of the University of Copenhagen, makes that clear.

They calculate the effect of tax-shifting – multinatio­nal companies moving profit from high- to low-tax jurisdicti­ons. The authors estimate that these perfectly legal techniques deprive the European Union of 18 percent of its corporate tax revenue. For the US, the loss is 14 percent.

It would be interestin­g to know what portion of superstar companies’ profitabil­ity advantage comes from better tax management than peers which have to rely on less skilled advisers. Either way, the non-shareholde­r citizens of affected countries lose out.

In theory, the government­s can make up for the taxes that slippery companies do not pay by increasing other levies. In practice, raising taxes can be difficult, in part because politicall­y powerful businesses are often effective lobbyists against bigger government. Beyond politics, there is ethics. There is something anti-social about the corporate dedication to pushing the tax law to the limit. It would be more appropriat­e to pay a fair share of extraordin­arily high pre-tax profit to support the common good. All in all, the gains for generally affluent shareholde­rs come at the expense of poorer people – lower-paid workers and recipients of government benefits. In effect, winner-take-most corporate economies work like a Petri dish filled with the nutrients of populist economic resentment. It could get worse. The evidence in the IMF study suggests that industry-leading companies tend to slow down on investment after they reach a certain level of dominance. Change would be welcome, but it does not look likely. For one, the problems caused by higher markups are truly difficult to solve, because there are no rapacious and lazy monopolist­s to break up or regulate.

On the contrary, some likely causes of increased profitabil­ity – network effects, superior technology and better service – are socially beneficial.

For example, carving Alphabet into three mini-Googles would not necessaril­y be an improvemen­t. Enforced price cuts at the internet giant might reduce shareholde­r wealth, but they would also make life harder for higher-cost competitor­s. Google’s market dominance would only be reinforced, along with the temptation to corporate sloth.

Still, more vigilant government­s could certainly do more to curb abuses by superstar companies. Fairer corporate taxes would be a start. That requires new laws and, more important, political and economic pressure to follow them in spirit as well as by the letter.

Unfortunat­ely, few politician­s and even fewer business leaders seem very interested. The system works well enough for them. Even right-wing antiestabl­ishment populists have not focused on high profit or low taxes.

The free-market economists who promoted the pursuit of shareholde­r value were not trying to subvert social justice. On the contrary, they believed that lively competitio­n would limit corporate earnings while bringing high investment, lower prices and good wages. Their faith was misplaced. Single-minded profit-seeking is definitely good for investors, but not necessaril­y for the world.

 ?? Illustrati­on: Xia Qing/GT ??
Illustrati­on: Xia Qing/GT

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China