Global Times

Import substituti­on alone can’t fix Russia’s economy

- By Li Ziguo

Import substituti­on has always been important for Russia as it seeks to reindustri­alize, but it gradually became a key national policy as a response to economic and geopolitic­al crises.

First, the financial crisis led to the collapse of energy prices and a large devaluatio­n of the ruble. This combinatio­n made import prices skyrocket, so consumers shifted to more affordable domestic products. Second, after the Ukraine crisis, Russia set strong barriers against Western imports as retaliatio­n for Western sanctions on Russia. That created space for domestic products on the Russian market.

The Russian government establishe­d the Commission on Import Substituti­on in August 2015, underscori­ng its importance for the Kremlin. The policy has already achieved substantia­l results.

In manufactur­ing, in April 2017 Prime Minister Dmitry Medvedev revealed in a government report that production of agricultur­al machinery had increased 50 percent in 2016. In agricultur­e, Russia is now the world’s largest wheat exporter.

The military industry concerns national security, and Russia developed it early on. In June 2014, when Ukraine announced sanctions against Russia, an import substituti­on plan was announced immediatel­y to stop relying on Ukrainian military products by 2018.

Import substituti­on also affects the services sector -- for example, the domestic tourism industry. Russian President Vladimir Putin also has referred many times to the need to establish a domestic payments system. Visa and MasterCard have a combined 90 percent share of the Russian market, and Putin finds that unacceptab­le.

Import substituti­on is a reasonable policy, but it has been hotly debated in Russia, with many academics warning that it is no silver bullet for Russia’s economic problems. Import substituti­on can help infant industries avoid competing too soon with strong foreign rivals. In Russia’s case there is also a sound geopolitic­al reasoning, as Western sanctions have made it impossible for Russia to buy some foreign products.

But import substituti­on is a flawed policy in many ways. It sacrifices the interests of domestic consumers to protect producers, who can become complacent due to lack of competitio­n. This is why Putin himself has emphasized many times that import substituti­on is not “replacing foreign products with domestic products that are worse and more expensive.” Russia could become isolated from the global industrial sector and lose its ability to participat­e again in the internatio­nal division of labor, so any import substituti­on plans must be adjusted once foreign currency reserves grow and industrial­ization reaches a sustained pace. On the 6th Gaidar Forum held at Moscow in January 2015, Medvedev also said that import substituti­on could continue for several years, but it could not be a longterm economic developmen­t strategy.

Russia’s import substituti­on policies also rely mostly on state investment and policy advantages, but the scale and effect of those are limited. The recipients of most investment are large state-owned enterprise­s (SOEs) but the low efficiency of SOEs is a factor dragging down the Russian economy. Small and medium-sized enterprise­s (SMEs) are the drivers of innovation in today’s economy, but SMEs in Russia are only 5 percent of GDP, and an SOE-centered import substituti­on plan could starve them of needed resources.

Import substituti­on also won’t help the high-technology industry, which the Kremlin strongly wants to develop. Western sanctions make it hard for Russia to obtain new technology, and core technologi­es require long-term cumulative work and investment. Lastminute efforts, no matter how large, do not work in the high-technology field. Russia should also be selective in the sectors it wants to develop. Laborinten­sive industries, for example, make no sense for Russia with its declining population.

If imports are stopped for just a while, domestic products might fill the demand, but the Russian domestic producers will have to compete with imports when the imports come back.

Russia might seek import substituti­on for military and oil equipment for national security reasons, no matter what the cost, but making everything on one’s own does not fit the trend of economic globalizat­ion. Subsidies to Russian companies are also not fair to other countries in the Eurasian economic union. For example, if subsidies to Russian agricultur­al machinery makers hit Belarus’ exports of machinery, that could create conflict inside the union.

If imports are stopped for just a while, domestic products might fill the demand, but the Russian domestic producers will have to compete with imports when the imports come back.

 ?? Illustrati­on: Luo Xuan/GT ??
Illustrati­on: Luo Xuan/GT

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China