Shanghai Daily

Long-term growth: economists vs scientists

- Kenneth Rogoff FOREIGN VIEWS

MOST economic forecaster­s have largely shrugged off recent advances in artificial intelligen­ce (for example, the quantum leap demonstrat­ed by DeepMind’s selflearni­ng chess program last December), seeing little impact on longer-term trend growth. Such pessimism is surely one of the reasons why real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates remain extremely low, even if the bellwether US 10-year bond rate has ticked up half a percentage point in the last few months. If supply-side pessimism is appropriat­e, the recent massive tax and spending packages in the United States will likely do much more to raise inflation than to boost investment.

There are plenty of reasons to object to recent US fiscal policy, even if lowering the corporate-tax rate made sense (albeit not by the amount enacted). Above all, we live in an era of rising inequality and falling income shares for labor relative to capital. Government­s need to do more, not less, to redistribu­te income and wealth.

It is hard to know what US President Donald Trump is thinking when he boasts that his policies will deliver up to 6 percent growth (unless he is talking about prices!). But if inflationa­ry pressures do indeed materializ­e, current growth might last significan­tly longer than forecaster­s and markets believe.

In any case, the focus of economists’ pessimism is long-term growth. Their stance is underpinne­d by the belief that advanced economies cannot hope to repeat the dynamism that the US enjoyed from 1995-2005 (and other advanced economies a bit later), much less the salad days of the 1950s and 1960s.

But the doubters ought to consider the fact that many scientists, across many discipline­s, see things differentl­y. Young researcher­s, in particular, believe that advances in basic knowledge are coming as fast as ever, even if practical applicatio­ns are taking a long time to develop. Indeed, a small but influentia­l cult touts the Hungarian-American mathematic­ian John von Neumann’s “singularit­y” theory. Someday, thinking machines will become so sophistica­ted that they will be able to invent other machines without any human interventi­on, and suddenly technology will advance exponentia­lly.

If so, perhaps we should be far more worried about the ethical and social implicatio­ns of material growth that is faster than humans can spirituall­y absorb. The angst over AI mostly focuses on inequality and the future of work. But as science fiction writers have long warned us, the potential threats arising from the birth of silicon-based “life” forms are truly frightenin­g.

It is hard to know who is right: neither economists nor scientists have a great track record when it comes to making long-term prediction­s. But right now, and leaving aside the possibilit­y of an existentia­l battle between man and machine, it seems quite plausible to expect a significan­t pickup in productivi­ty growth over the next five years.

Consider that the main components of economic growth are increases in the labor force, increases in investment (both public and private), and “productivi­ty,” namely the output than can be produced with a given amount of inputs, thanks to new ideas. Over the past 10-15 years, all three have been dismally low in the advanced economies.

Catalyst for change

Labor force growth has slowed sharply, owing to declining birth rates, with immigratio­n failing to compensate even in pre-Trump America. The influx of women into the labor force played a major role in boosting growth in the latter part of the twentieth century. But now that has largely played out, although government­s could do more to support female labor force participat­ion and pay equity.

Similarly, global investment has collapsed since the 2008 financial crisis (though not in China), lowering potential growth. And measured productivi­ty growth has declined everywhere, falling roughly by half in the US since the tech boom of the mid-1990s. No wonder global real interest rates are so low, with high post-crisis savings chasing a smaller supply of investment opportunit­ies.

Still, the best bet is that AI and other new technologi­es will eventually come to have a much larger impact on growth than they have up to now. It is well known that it can take a very long time for businesses to reimagine productive processes to exploit new technologi­es: railroads and electricit­y are two leading examples. The pickup in global growth is likely to be a catalyst for change, creating incentives for firms to invest and introduce new technologi­es, some of which will substitute for labor, offsetting the slowdown in the growth of the workforce.

With the after-effects of the financial crisis fading, and AI perhaps starting to gain traction, trend US output growth can easily stay strong for the next several years (though, of course, a recession is also possible). The likely correspond­ing rise in real global interest rates will be tricky for central bankers to navigate. In the best case, they will be able to “ride the wave,” as Alan Greenspan famously did in the 1990s, though more inflation is likely this time.

The bottom line is that neither policymake­rs nor markets should be betting on the slow growth of the past decade carrying over to the next. But that might not be entirely welcome news. If the scientists are right, we may come to regret the growth we get.

Kenneth Rogoff, a former chief economist of the IMF, is Professor of Economics and Public Policy at Harvard University. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2018. www.project-syndicate.org

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from China