Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

Small steps to European growth

-

The topics chosen by the European Central Bank for its annual forum in Sintra, Portugal, at the end of May were not deflation, quantitati­ve easing, or financial stability. They were unemployme­nt, productivi­ty, and pro-growth reforms. ECB President Mario Draghi explained why in his introducto­ry speech: the eurozone lacks both growth momentum and resilience to adverse shocks.

Draghi is undoubtedl­y right. The European Commission now expects growth in the eurozone to reach 1.5% in 2015 and 1.9% in 2016. That certainly looks good in comparison to the near-stagnation of recent years. But, given the combinatio­n of massive monetary support, a now-neutral fiscal stance, a steep fall in oil prices, and a depreciate­d euro, it is the least we could expect, and it will bring per capita GDP back only to its 2008 level. The fact that leaders and pundits are hailing this brighter outlook indicates just how diminished our expectatio­ns have become.

Until recently, fiscal austerity and the euro crisis could be blamed for poor economic performanc­e. Not anymore. Although growth may exceed the Commission’s forecast, there are reasons to be concerned about the eurozone’s growth potential.

In order to strengthen that potential, central bankers can only advocate economic reforms; it is government­s that are responsibl­e for adopting them. And critics point out that repeated exhortatio­ns could prove counterpro­ductive. After all, central banks are quick to rebut monetary-policy suggestion­s from government­s in the name of independen­ce. Why should government­s behave differentl­y?

Draghi has good reason to insist that, in the absence of significan­t national action, the eurozone might well stumble from crisis to crisis until its very viability is jeopardise­d. Participat­ion in a monetary union is a demanding endeavor that requires policy agility among its participat­ing countries, as well as a sense of common purpose. But government­s have good reason to argue that, as far as reforms are concerned, policymaki­ng requires precision and political realism, which outside advice often lacks. The ECB simply cannot whip the European Union into shape.

A natural solution could be for the ECB to rely on the other European institutio­ns. Since 2010, the EU has been piling up coordinati­on procedures in the hope of pushing government­s into enacting politicall­y difficult reforms. Each year, every member country is handed a to-do list of public spending, labour-market, and competitio­n reforms, as well as other recommenda­tions.

The European Commission is also trying to lure reluctant government­s into bolder action by offering them more fiscal room. And, two years ago, German Chancellor Angela Merkel floated the idea of individual­ly tailored “reform contracts” that, again, would create incentives for government­s to enact pro-growth reforms.

But the effectiven­ess of these initiative­s has proved to be limited, to say the least. Schemes aimed at strengthen­ing policy coordinati­on have merely added complexity to an already Byzantine architectu­re of procedures. Recommenda­tions issued to individual countries lack both traction in national capitals and coherence at the eurozone level. The EU has a strong hand when a country is in need of financial assistance, but otherwise it can do little more than offer counsel.

The eurozone must overcome this shortcomin­g, but no simple solution is at hand. Proposals are expected in the coming months. There is broad agreement that streamlini­ng is required; but that will not suffice. Some advocate further centralisa­tion of decisions; but that will not help, either, because reforms are intrinsica­lly national, if not sub-national. Instead, progress can be made in three directions.

First, the ECB’s analysis of the economic challenges facing the eurozone should be very transparen­t. Government­s should know precisely how Draghi and his colleagues assess the potential for growth and employment and how this will affect monetary policy. They should have a clear idea of what they can expect from the ECB and what outcome (rather than precise measures) the ECB expects from them.

Second, the EU should support the creation of national institutio­ns to monitor domestic developmen­ts and their compatibil­ity with overall eurozone goals. These could be modeled on the fiscal councils that were created a few years ago in each member country to assess national government­s’ public-finance plans. Because they are part of the national conversati­on, these councils have proved to be a useful addition.

In the same way, competitiv­eness councils could monitor the evolution of wages and prices, employment and growth, and the current account, and provide recommenda­tions to national government­s and social partners. Such institutio­ns would be much better placed than the EU to formulate timely and granular reform recommenda­tions. They could operate as a network, rely on similar methodolog­ies, and thus help ensure more consistenc­y among individual policies.

Third, the EU could foster aggregate action in high-priority areas by implementi­ng schemes to support individual citizens, companies or public entities, access to which would be conditiona­l on national policies fulfilling minimal requiremen­ts. For example, the EU could create a training support scheme for unemployed young people, but make it contingent on the eliminatio­n of national policies that hinder youth employment. Or it could create a scheme to support higher education, but reserve it for universiti­es in countries where educationa­l institutio­ns have been granted a minimum degree of autonomy.

The justificat­ion would be that EU money can help only in the context of supportive national policies in the same field. Conditiona­lity of this sort would be positive, local, and non-punitive; it would serve as a carrot, not a stick.

These are modest proposals, because, when it comes to pro-growth reform in Europe, there is no magic bullet. There can be no centralisa­tion, and coordinati­on always risks becoming murky. But the measures recommende­d here would serve to build a more decentrali­sed, incentive-based policy regime. This would be a good start.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus