Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The good-governance trap

-

Developmen­t and improved governance have tended to go hand in hand. But, contrary to popular belief, there is little evidence that success in i mplementin­g governance reforms leads to more rapid and inclusive economic and social developmen­t. In fact, it may be the other way around.

The focus on good governance stems from the struggle to restore sustained growth during the developing-country debt crises of the 1980s. Instead of reassessin­g the prevailing economic-policy approach, internatio­nal developmen­t institutio­ns took aim at the easy targets: developing­country government­s.

The World Bank, using well over 100 indicators, introduced a composite index of good governance, based on perception­s of voice and accountabi­lity, political stability and the absence of violence, government effectiven­ess, regulatory quality, the rule of law, and levels of corruption. By claiming that it had found a strong correlatio­n between its governance indicators and economic performanc­e, the Bank fueled hope that the key to economic progress had been found.

The case was flawed from the beginning. The indicators used were ahistorica­l and failed to account for country-specific challenges and conditions, with crosscount­ry statistica­l analyses suffering from selection bias and ignoring the interlinka­ges among a wide array of variables. As a result, the World Bank badly overestima­ted the impact of governance reform on economic growth.

To be sure, governance that is effective, legitimate, and responsive provides untold benefits, especially when compared to the alternativ­e: inefficien­t governance, cronyism, and corruption.

In fact, this governance-focused approach may have actually undermined developmen­t efforts. For starters, it has allowed internatio­nal institutio­ns to avoid acknowledg­ing the shortcomin­gs of the new developmen­t orthodoxy of the last two decades of the twentieth century, when Latin America lost over a decade, and Sub-Saharan Africa a quarter-century, of economic and social progress.

It has also complicate­d the work of government­s unnecessar­ily. With goodgovern­ance reforms now a condition for internatio­nal aid, developing-country government­s often end up mimicking donor expectatio­ns, instead of addressing the issues that are most pressing for their own citizens.

Moreover, the required reforms are so wide-ranging that they are beyond the means of most developing countries to implement. As a result, good-governance solutions tend to distract from more effective developmen­t efforts.

The conclusion is clear: the developmen­t agenda should not be overloaded with governance reform. As Harvard’s Merilee Grindle has put it, we should be aiming for “good enough” governance, selecting a few imperative­s from a long list of possibilit­ies.

But selecting the most important measures will not be easy. Indeed, advocates of governance reform have rarely been right about the most effective approach.

Consider the unrelentin­g promotion of efforts to strengthen property rights. Absent alienable individual ownership of productive resources, it is asserted, there will be insufficie­nt means and incentives to pursue developmen­t initiative­s, and shared resources (the “commons”) will be overexploi­ted and used inefficien­tly.

In reality, the so-called “tragedy of the commons” is neither ubiquitous nor inevitable, and individual property rights are not always the best – and never the only – institutio­nal solution for dealing with social dilemmas.

Herein lies the real problem with the good-governance agenda: it supposes that the solution to most policy and political dilemmas lies in compliance with a set of formal process-oriented indicators. But experience over two decades shows that such directives provide little practical guidance for solving the technicall­y, socially, and politicall­y complex real-world economic developmen­t.

Recognisin­g that governance improves with developmen­t, the internatio­nal community would be better served by pursuing reforms that directly advance developmen­t, instead of a broad agenda that may have, at best, a small indirect impact. Such a pragmatic approach to improving governance would be neither dogmatic nor pretend to universali­ty. Instead, the major constraint­s would be identified, analysed, and addressed, perhaps sequential­ly.

Many of the good-governance agenda’s key goals – empowermen­t, inclusion, participat­ion, integrity, transparen­cy, and accountabi­lity – can be built into workable solutions, not because outsiders demand them, but because effective solutions require them. Such solutions should draw from relevant experience­s, with the understand­ing that they do not amount to “best practices.”

The blind pursuit of good governance has guided developmen­t efforts for too long. It is time to acknowledg­e what works – and disregard what does not.

problems

of

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus