Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

What to expect in 2016:

Political will to preserve Eurozone remains strong Recovery has arrived, but growth is well below pre-crisis trend The external risks are significan­t, too

-

In anticipati­ng macroecono­mic conditions for the Eurozone in 2016, three themes are relevant. The first is that the political will to preserve the Eurozone, and to deepen European economic integratio­n, appears to be as strong as ever. Since the start of the Eurozone debt crisis in 2008, this political will has been underestim­ated. This also largely explains why during the crisis DBRS maintained its sovereign ratings on Italy, Spain, Ireland and Portugal higher those of other credit rating agencies.

During the crisis DBRS downgraded these ratings, but no lower than ‘Single A (low)’ in the cases of Italy, Spain and Ireland, and no lower than ‘BBB (low)’ in the case of Portugal.

There is some evidence to support the theory that the more Europe is tested, the greater the impetus to deepen integratio­n. Integratio­n is in fact proceeding in both fiscal policy and financial policy. The European Commission has a mandate to impose sanctions on countries that do not adhere to the Stability and Growth Pact. However, the treatment of member states’ budgets is complex and allows for significan­t exceptions to the rules. For example, the Commission’s November 2015 assessment of the member states’ 2016 draft budgetary plans permits higher incrementa­l spending linked to unusual events outside the control of the government, such as the exceptiona­l inflow of refugees. However, only some member states have included the net extra costs of the refugee crisis in their draft budgetary plans. While greater fiscal flexibilit­y may be appropriat­e to accommodat­e cyclical downturns or unexpected shocks such as the influx of refugees, the applicatio­n of the rules is unclear.

To enforce oversight, the forthcomin­g European Fiscal Board will coordinate the monitoring of national budgets with national fiscal councils. Presumably, this should improve the monitoring of member states’ budgets, and could result in greater consistenc­y of the applicatio­n of the fiscal rules across member states.

Greater integratio­n is also occurring with the banking union. The supervisor­y pillar is in place and the resolution mechanism is being implemente­d. As of January 1, 2016, all member states will apply a single rulebook for the resolution of banks and large investment firms as part of the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive. The BRRD requires shareholde­rs and creditors of banks to contribute to the costs of a failing institutio­n through a bail-in mechanism. Although this could dissuade investors from purchasing shares or bonds, these rules are neverthele­ss likely to make the winding down of a bankrupt financial institutio­n more predictabl­e.

The Eurozone’s evolving financial backstop, in the form of ECB monetary accommodat­ion and the support facilities, is further evidence of willingnes­s to preserve the Eurozone. The ECB’s extraordin­ary monetary accommodat­ion has been the single most important factor in stabilizin­g the region, from the Securities Markets Program to the promise of Outright Monetary Transactio­ns – Governor Mario Draghi’s July 2012 statement that the ECB would do “whatever it takes to preserve the Euro” – to Quantitati­ve Easing (QE). The EFSF and ESM financial backstops rolled out since the first support programme for Greece also demonstrat­ed this willingnes­s. These programmes may not have necessaril­y restored debt sustainabi­lity in all cases, but they did stem the panic and prevent contagion to other countries. The preservati­on of Greece and Cyprus as member states in the Eurozone further demonstrat­ed this willingnes­s.

The second theme is that the recovery has arrived, but GDP growth is well below the pre-crisis trend. The IMF’s October World Economic Outlook GDP growth projection­s appear to be reasonable: the IMF expects the world economy to grow by 3.1% this year and 3.6% next year, while in the Eurozone growth is expected at 1.5% this year and 1.6% next year. In the third quarter, the Eurozone grew 0.3% quarteron-quarter, slowing from 0.4% in the second quarter. Yearon-year, the Eurozone grew 1.6%, slightly higher than 1.5% in the second quarter. As Exhibit 1 shows, the United States and United Kingdom are growing well above their pre-crisis peak; the EU has just surpassed it; the Eurozone and Japan not quite. This is an uneven picture, and the uncertaint­ies facing the Eurozone present downside risks to growth.

Indeed, it is doubtful that the Eurozone has emerged stronger after the crisis. When the output gap closes, it is likely to do so at a lower level of output. As Exhibit 2 shows, the dotted black line represents the slope of potential GDP as it would have been had the crisis not occurred; the yellow line is the new projected rate of growth of the economy; the blue line below is the actual rate of growth. The output gap – the gap between the blue line and the yellow line – is expected to close at a lower level of output than it would have given the original projected potential GDP. By one measure, the loss to potential GDP for a selection of 22 advanced economies is 8.4% below the pre-crisis path would have predicted.

The question is, why has trend growth declined? One would expect a rebound in exports given the weaker exchange rate, higher consumptio­n and investment from lower world oil and commodity prices, and greater consumptio­n and lending from low interest rates because of bond purchases by the ECB. However, domestic demand has yet to rebound in a more robust manner. The most convincing argument for why growth in the Eurozone is so far below potential is the “savings glut” argument – “secular stagnation” – or the tendency for demand to be weak relative to potential supply.

Weak domestic demand, supply side constraint­s, and political fragmentat­ion may all be contributi­ng to this phenomenon. Despite some signs of a pickup in consumptio­n, both consumptio­n and investment remain lacklustre. This deficient domestic demand is at least partly the result of deleveragi­ng government­s, households, nonfinanci­al corporatio­ns and banks. In such an environmen­t, it is no surprise that spending is lower. Second, with low investment, especially public investment, labour productivi­ty has declined. Exhibit 3 shows that the labor productivi­ty growth that is attributab­le to investment has declined sharply in the G7 countries – not only in the US, the UK and Japan, but also in Germany, France, Italy and Spain. Therefore, this is a worldwide phenomenon. With lower productivi­ty comes lower growth.

Second, there are significan­t supply side constraint­s. One sign of this is in persistent unemployme­nt, which is affecting human capital. For long-term unemployed, inactive or discourage­d workers, their adverse experience may negatively affect their attitude toward work, as well as their aptitude for work. The risk is that in the event of persistent low growth, or worse, a severe downturn, the bad cycle might permanentl­y damage the trend. An equally important supply side constraint is sluggish credit growth. In spite of QE, which has kept bond yields low and expanded the ECB’s balance sheet, credit growth to households and non-financial corporatio­ns has been limited.

A third possible reason for low growth is political fragmentat­ion. There have been several layers of fragmentat­ion. Austerity fatigue and other factors are resulting in the splinterin­g of traditiona­l centrist political parties, and this is drawing mainstream politician­s to the

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus