Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

Monopoly’s new era

-

For 200 years, there have been two schools of thought about what determines the distributi­on of income – and how the economy functions. One, emanating from Adam Smith and nineteenth-century liberal economists, focuses on competitiv­e markets. The other, cognisant of how Smith’s brand of liberalism leads to rapid concentrat­ion of wealth and income, takes as its starting point unfettered markets’ tendency toward monopoly. It is important to understand both, because our views about government policies and existing inequaliti­es are shaped by which of the two schools of thought one believes provides a better descriptio­n of reality.

For the nineteenth-century liberals and their latter-day acolytes, because markets are competitiv­e, individual­s’ returns are related to their social contributi­ons – their “marginal product,” in the language of economists. Capitalist­s are rewarded for saving rather than consuming – for their abstinence, in the words of Nassau Senior, one of my predecesso­rs in the Drummond Professors­hip of Political Economy at Oxford. Difference­s in income were then related to their ownership of “assets” – human and financial capital. Scholars of inequality thus focused on the determinan­ts of the distributi­on of assets, including how they are passed on across generation­s.

The second school of thought takes as its starting point “power,” including the ability to exercise monopoly control or, in labour markets, to assert authority over workers. Scholars in this area have focused on what gives rise to power, how it is maintained and strengthen­ed, and other features that may prevent markets from being competitiv­e. Work on exploitati­on arising from asymmetrie­s of informatio­n is an important example.

In the West in the post-World War II era, the liberal school of thought has dominated. Yet, as inequality has widened and concerns about it have grown, the competitiv­e school, viewing individual returns in terms of marginal product, has become increasing­ly unable to explain how the economy works. So, today, the second school of thought is ascendant.

After all, the large bonuses paid to banks’ CEOs as they led their firms to ruin and the economy to the brink of collapse are hard to reconcile with the belief that individual­s’ pay has anything to do with their social contributi­ons. Of course, historical­ly, the oppression of large groups – slaves, women, and minorities of various types – are obvious instances where inequaliti­es are the result of power relationsh­ips, not marginal returns.

In today’s economy, many sectors – telecoms, cable TV, digital branches from social media to Internet search, health insurance, pharmaceut­icals, agro-business, and many more – cannot be understood through the lens of competitio­n. In these sectors, what competitio­n exists is oligopolis­tic, not the “pure” competitio­n depicted in textbooks. A few sectors can be defined as “price taking”; firms are so small that they have no effect on market price. Agricultur­e is the clearest example, but government interventi­on in the sector is massive, and prices are not set primarily by market forces.

US President Barack Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers, led by Jason Furman, has attempted to tally the extent of the increase in market concentrat­ion and some of its implicatio­ns. In most industries, according to the CEA, standard metrics show large – and in some cases, dramatic – increases in market concentrat­ion. The top ten banks’ share of the deposit market, for example, increased from about 20% to 50% in just 30 years, from 1980 to 2010.

Some of the increase in market power is the result of changes in technology and economic structure: consider network economies and the growth of locally provided service-sector industries. Some is because firms – Microsoft and drug companies are good examples – have learned better how to erect and maintain entry barriers, often assisted by conservati­ve political forces that justify lax anti-trust enforcemen­t and the failure to limit market power on the grounds that markets are “naturally” competitiv­e. And some of it reflects the naked abuse and leveraging of market power through the political process: large banks, for example, lobbied the US Congress to amend or repeal legislatio­n separating commercial banking from other areas of finance.

The consequenc­es are evident in the data, with inequality rising at every level, not only across individual­s, but also across firms. The CEA report noted that the “90th percentile firm sees returns on investment­s in capital that are more than five times the median. This ratio was closer to two just a quarter of a century ago.”

Joseph Schumpeter, one of the great economists of the twentieth century, argued that one shouldn’t be worried by monopoly power: monopolies would only be temporary. There would be fierce competitio­n for the market and this would replace competitio­n in the market and ensure that prices remained competitiv­e.

My own theoretica­l work long ago showed the flaws in Schumpeter’s analysis, and now empirical results provide strong confirmati­on. Today’s markets are characteri­sed by the persistenc­e of high monopoly profits.

The implicatio­ns of this are profound. Many of the assumption­s about market economies are based on acceptance of the competitiv­e model, with marginal returns commensura­te with social contributi­ons. This view has led to hesitancy about official interventi­on: If markets are fundamenta­lly efficient and fair, there is little that even the best of government­s could do to improve matters. But if markets are based on exploitati­on, the rationale for laissezfai­re disappears. Indeed, in that case, the battle against entrenched power is not only a battle for democracy; it is also a battle for efficiency and shared prosperity.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus