Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The oversellin­g of Financial Transactio­n Tax

-

However November’s presidenti­al election in the United States turns out, one proposal that will likely live on is the introducti­on of a financial transactio­n tax (FTT). While by no means a crazy idea, an FTT is hardly the panacea that its hard-left advocates hold it out to be. It is certainly a poor substitute for deeper tax reform aimed at making the system simpler, more transparen­t, and more progressiv­e.

As American society ages and domestic inequality worsens, and assuming that interest rates on the national debt eventually rise, taxes will need to go up, urgently on the wealthy but some day on the middle class. There is no magic wand, and the politicall­y expedient idea of a “Robin Hood” tax on trading is being badly oversold.

True, a number of advanced countries already use FTTs of one sort or another. The United Kingdom has had a “stamp tax” on stock sales for centuries, and the US had one from 1914 to 1964. The European Union has a controvers­ial plan on the drawing boards that would tax a much broader array of transactio­ns.

The presidenti­al campaign of US Senator Bernie Sanders, which dominates the intellectu­al debate in the Democratic Party, has argued for a broad-based tax covering stocks, bonds, and derivative­s (which include a vast array of more complex instrument­s such as options and swaps). The claim is that such a tax will help repress the forces that led to the financial crisis, raise a surreal amount of revenue to pay for progressiv­e causes, and barely impact middle-class taxpayers.

So far, Hillary Clinton, the likely Democratic nominee, has embraced a narrower version that would target mainly highspeed traders, who account for a large percentage of all stock transactio­ns, and whose contributi­on to social welfare is open to question. Clinton, however, may well shift closer to Sanders’s position over time, as she has on other issues. Donald Trump, the presumptiv­e Republican nominee, has not yet articulate­d a coherent position on the topic, but his views often come down remarkably close to those of Sanders.

The idea of taxing financial transactio­ns dates back to John Maynard Keynes in the 1930s and was taken up by Yale professor and Nobel laureate James Tobin (who, incidental­ly, was my undergradu­ate professor) in the 1970s. The idea, in Tobin’s words, was to “throw sand in the wheels” of financial markets to slow them down and make them hew more closely to economic fundamenta­ls.

Unfortunat­ely, this rationale has not held up particular­ly well either in theory or in practice. Particular­ly misguided is the idea that FTTs would have significan­tly muted the buildup to the 2008 financial crisis. Centuries of experience with financial crises, including in countries with FTTs, strongly suggests otherwise. What is really needed is better regulation of financial markets. The unwieldy and deeply imperfect 2010 Dodd Frank legislatio­n, with its thousands of pages of provisions, is a stopgap measure; few serious people view it as a long-term solution. A far better idea is to force financial firms to issue much more equity (stock), as Stanford University’s Anat Admati has proposed.

The more banks are forced to evaluate risks based on shareholde­r losses rather than government bailouts, the safer the system will be. (On this score, Boston University professor Laurence Kotlikoff’s more radical ideas for taking leverage out of the financial system merit serious attention, even if his own quixotic presidenti­al campaign otherwise goes unnoticed).

The fundamenta­l problem with FTTs is that they are distortion­ary; for example, by driving down stock prices, they make raising capital more expensive for firms. In the long run, this lowers labour productivi­ty and wage levels. True, all taxes are distorting, and the government has to raise money somehow. Yet economists view FTTs as particular­ly troublesom­e because they distort intermedia­te activity, which amplifies their effects. A modest tax that is narrowly targeted, like the UK’s, does not seem to cause much harm; but the revenue is modest.

To get more revenue requires casting the net much wider. For this reason, the Sanders plan covers derivative instrument­s that would circumvent the FTT (for example, by allowing people to trade income streams on assets without trading ownership). But extending the tax to derivative­s is a messy business, because their complexiti­es make it difficult to define precisely what should be taxed. And as the impact of the tax expands, it becomes hard to know what the ultimate effects on the real economy will be.

It is certainly difficult to determine whether the outsize revenue estimates of the Sanders campaign could be realised; many studies suggest otherwise. The claim is that the US can collect more than five times the amount the UK collects on its narrow tax – an amount equal to more than 10% of revenue from personal income tax. The problem is that trading will likely collapse in many areas, and many financial trades will be executed in other countries. If economic growth is affected, eventually other tax revenues will fall, and if government bonds are covered, borrowing costs will rise.

The US desperatel­y needs comprehens­ive tax reform, ideally a progressiv­e tax on consumptio­n. In any case, a properly designed FTT can be no more than a small part of a much larger strategy, whether for reforming the tax system or for regulating financial markets.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus