Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The lost lesson of the 2007 financial crisis

-

Ten years ago, the French bank BNP Paribas decided to limit investors’ access to the money they had deposited in three funds. It was the first loud signal of the financial stress that would, a year later, send the global economy into a tailspin. Yet the massive economic and financial dislocatio­ns that would come to a boil in late 2008 and continue through early 2009 – which brought the world to the brink of a devastatin­g multi-year depression – took policymake­rs in advanced economies completely by surprise. They had clearly not paid enough attention to the lessons of crises in the emerging world.

Anyone who has experience­d or studied developing­country financial crises will be painfully aware of their defining features. For starters, as the late Rüdiger Dornbusch argued, financial crises can take a long time to develop, but once they erupt, they tend to spread rapidly, widely, violently, and (seemingly) indiscrimi­nately.

In this process of cascading failures, overall financial conditions quickly flip from feast to famine. Private credit factories that seemed indestruct­ible are brought to their knees, and central banks and government­s are confronted with tough, inherently uncertain policy choices. Moreover, policymake­rs also have to account for the risk of a “sudden stop” to economic activity, which can devastate employment, trade, and investment.

Marshallin­g a sufficient­ly comprehens­ive response to extreme financial stress becomes even more difficult, if not enough was done during the good times to ensure sustainabl­e and inclusive growth. It becomes harder still when politician­s are actively playing the blame game. In the end, the sociopolit­ical and institutio­nal effects of a crisis can far outlast the economic and financial ones.

All of these lessons would have been useful to advancedec­onomy policymake­rs ten years ago. When BNP Paribas froze $2.2 bln worth of funds on August 9, 2007, it should have been obvious that more financial stress would be forthcomin­g. But policymake­rs drew the wrong conclusion­s, primarily for two reasons.

First, it took some time for policymake­rs to come to grips with the extent of the financial system’s latent instabilit­y, which had accumulate­d under their watch. Second, most policymake­rs in the advanced world were too dismissive of the idea that they had anything to learn from emerging countries’ experience­s.

Unfortunat­ely, these problems are yet to be fully resolved. In fact, there is a growing risk that politician­s – many of whom are distracted and sidesteppi­ng their economicgo­vernance responsibi­lities – may be missing the biggest historical insight of all: the importance of an economy’s underlying growth model.

Indeed, advanced-country politician­s today still seem to be ignoring the limitation­s of an economic model that relies excessivel­y on finance to create sustainabl­e, inclusive growth. Though those limitation­s have been laid bare over the last ten years, policymake­rs did not strengthen adequately the growth model on which their economies depend. Instead, they often acted as if the crisis was merely a cyclical – albeit dramatic – shock, and assumed that the economy would bounce back in a V-like fashion, as it had typically done after a recession.

Because policymake­rs were initially captivated by cyclical thinking, they did not regard the financial crisis as a secular or epochal event. The result was that they purposely designed their policy responses to be “timely, targeted, and temporary.” Eventually, it became clear that the problem required a much broader, longer-term structural solution. But by that time, the political window of opportunit­y for bold actions had essentiall­y closed.

Consequent­ly, advanced economies took too long returning to pre-crisis GDP levels, and were unable to unleash their considerab­le growth potential. Worse, the growth that they did achieve in the years after the crisis was not inclusive; instead, the excessivel­y wide income, wealth, and opportunit­y gaps in many advanced economies endured.

The longer this pattern persisted, the more advanced economies’ future growth prospects suffered. And what was previously unthinkabl­e – both financiall­y and politicall­y – started to become possible, even likely.

A decade after the start of the crisis, advanced economies still have not decisively pivoted away from a growth model that is overly reliant on liquidity and leverage – first from private financial institutio­ns, and then from central banks. They have yet to make sufficient investment­s in infrastruc­ture, education, and human capital more generally. They have not addressed anti-growth distortion­s that undermine the efficacy of tax systems, financial intermedia­tion, and trade. And they have failed to keep up with technology, taking advantage of the potential benefits of big data, machine learning, artificial intelligen­ce, and new forms of mobility, while managing effectivel­y the related risks.

Policymake­rs in the advanced world lagged in internalis­ing the relevant insights from emerging economies. But they now have the evidence and analytical capability to do so. It is in their power to avert more disappoint­ments, tap into sources of sustainabl­e growth, and tackle today’s alarming levels of inequality. The ball is in the political class’s court.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus