Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

How can we tax footloose multinatio­nals?

Apple, Google, Starbucks, and companies like them all claim to be socially responsibl­e, but the first element of social responsibi­lity should be paying your fair share of tax. Instead, globalisat­ion has enabled multinatio­nals to encourage a race to the bo

- By Joseph E. Stiglitz

Apple has become the poster child for corporate tax avoidance, with its legal claim that a few hundred people working in Ireland were the real source of its profits, and then striking a deal with that country’s government that resulted in its paying a tax amounting to .005% of its profit. Apple, Google, Starbucks, and companies like them all claim to be socially responsibl­e, but the first element of social responsibi­lity should be paying your fair share of tax. If everyone avoided and evaded taxes like these companies, society could not function, much less make the public investment­s that led to the Internet, on which Apple and Google depend.

For years, multinatio­nal corporatio­ns have encouraged a race to the bottom, telling each country that it must lower its taxes below that of its competitor­s. US President Donald Trump’s 2017 tax cut culminated that race. A year later, we can see the results: the sugar high it brought to the US economy is quickly fading, leaving behind a mountain of debt (which increased by more than $1 trln last year).

Spurred on by the threat that the digital economy will deprive government­s of the revenues to fund function (as well as distorting the economy away from traditiona­l ways of selling), the internatio­nal community is at long last recognizin­g that something is wrong. But the flaws in the current framework of multinatio­nal taxation – based on socalled transfer pricing – have long been known.

Transfer pricing relies on the well-accepted principle that taxes should reflect where an economic activity occurs. But how is that determined? In a globalised economy, products move repeatedly across borders, typically in an unfinished state: a shirt without buttons, a car without a transmissi­on, a wafer without a chip. The transfer price system assumes that we can establish arms-length values for each stage of production, and thereby assess the value added within a country. But we can’t.

The growing role of intellectu­al property and intangible­s makes matters even worse, because ownership claims can easily be moved around the world. That’s why the United States long ago abandoned using the transfer price system within the US, in favor of a formula that attributes companies’ total profits to each state in proportion to the share of sales, employment, and capital there. We need to move toward such a system at the global level.

How that is actually done, however, makes a great deal of difference. If the formula is based largely on final sales, which occur disproport­ionately in developed countries, developing countries will be deprived of needed revenues, which will be increasing­ly missed as fiscal constraint­s diminish aid flows. Final sales may be appropriat­e for taxation of digital transactio­ns, but not for manufactur­ing or other sectors, where it is vital to include employment as well.

Some worry that including employment might exacerbate tax competitio­n, as government­s seek to encourage multinatio­nals to create jobs in their jurisdicti­ons. The appropriat­e response to this concern is to impose a global minimum corporate-income tax. The US and the European Union could – and should – do this on their own. If they did, others would follow, preventing a race in which only the multinatio­nals win.

Since its inception, the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project has made an important contributi­on to rethinking the taxation of multinatio­nals by advancing understand­ing of some of the fundamenta­l issues. For example, if there is true value in multinatio­nals, the whole is greater than the sum of the parts. Standard tax principles of simplicity, efficiency, and equity should guide our thinking in allocating the “residual value,” as the Independen­t Commission for the Reform of Internatio­nal Corporate Taxation (of which I am a member) advocates. But these principles are inconsiste­nt either with retaining the transfer price system or with basing taxes primarily on sales.

Politics matters: the multinatio­nals’ objective is to gain support for reforms that continue the race to the bottom and maintain opportunit­ies for tax avoidance. Government­s in some advanced countries where these companies have significan­t political influence will support these efforts – even if doing so disadvanta­ges the rest of the country. Other advanced countries, focusing on their own budgets, will simply see this as another opportunit­y to benefit at the expense of developing countries.

The OECD/G20 initiative refers to its efforts as providing an “Inclusive Framework.” Such a framework must be guided by principles, not just politics. If the goal is genuine inclusiven­ess, the top priority must be the wellbeing of the more than six billion people living in developing countries and emerging markets. Joseph E. Stiglitz, a Nobel laureate in economics, is University Professor at Columbia University and Chief Economist at the Roosevelt Institute. His most recent book is “Globalizat­ion and Its Discontent­s Revisited: Anti-Globalizat­ion in the Era of Trump”.

© Project Syndicate, 2018. www.project-syndicate.org

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus