Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

The case for carbon import taxes

- By Ed Araral and Vinod Thomas Ed Araral is an associate professor at the National University of Singapore’s Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy. Vinod Thomas is a visiting professor at the National University of Singapore’s Lee Kuan Yew School of Public

Taxing the carbon content of imports, as the European Union plans to do and US President Joe Biden’s administra­tion is considerin­g, can help to dent the rising trend in global greenhouse-gas emissions. But policymake­rs must implement such levies in the right way.

By focusing on emissions linked to consumptio­n, rather than just domestic production, such taxes would target the roughly one-fifth of import-related emissions usually excluded from calculatio­ns of countries’ nationally determined contributi­ons under the 2015 Paris climate agreement. They would also be timely, given the growing divergence between consumptio­n- and production-based emissions. Since 1990, for example, US production-based emissions have increased by 3%, while the country’s consumptio­n-based emissions rose by 14% over the same period.

Carbon tariffs are not protection­ist trade measures; the goal is to reduce the carbon content of imports. But the trajectory of climate change leaves no room for error in emission-reduction policies. The success of initial EU and US steps to introduce carbon border taxes is therefore crucial, because these measures will serve as a model for others. In particular, policymake­rs must heed some essential principles that should govern such levies.

For starters, a carbon border tariff should be driven by the benefit-cost calculus in favor of pricing the negative “externalit­y,” or spillover harm – namely, the carbon content – into the production of imported goods. Generally, import levies to protect domestic industries raise the cost of production, and hurt consumers’ welfare. In contrast, import tariffs that reduce carbon dioxide emissions would improve global welfare, with these gains exceeding the losses from trade inhibition. Carbon tariffs must not be perceived as constituti­ng part of a trade war, but rather as contributi­ng to collaborat­ive pricing of a socially harmful activity.

That means that policymake­rs must keep an eye on these levies’ primary purpose. They must design tariffs to regulate the carbon content of imported goods, rather than to protect domestic industries or provide them with an implicit subsidy. Tariffs should focus on the emissions embodied in the imports, not on domestic industry’s cost disadvanta­ge or the likelihood of production moving abroad.

That is why government­s should never use carbon tariffs as blunt instrument­s to hit imports. For example, blocking steel imports from China or India is a crude and costly way to reduce those countries’ emissions compared to a carbonrela­ted tariff that motivates exporters to switch to lesspollut­ing production methods.

The effect of the carbon tariff on emissions in the exporting country depends on that country’s ability to divert its exports to other markets. To maximize the global environmen­tal gains, therefore, it is vital that as many countries as possible are part of the new tariff regime. Because some importing countries like Germany and Canada, as well as some US states, have domestic carbon taxes or carbon-trading systems, the goal could be to align carbon import tariffs with these carbon-pricing instrument­s.

In fact, there is a synergisti­c link between a carbon border tariff, a domestic carbon tax, and domestic and internatio­nal carbon credits, the three market-oriented tools for carbon abatement. As domestic carbon taxes or carbon credits (or both) help to reduce CO2 emissions, the effective import tariff collected would decline because imports would contain less carbon.

Iron, steel, and petroleum products are the most carboninte­nsive imports – and China, Russia, and India export the most carbon-intensive iron and steel. The top importers in this category are China, the United States, and the EU. But their sources of supply are diversifie­d: the leading iron and steel exporters to the US are Canada, Brazil, and Mexico, for example. Major importers of highly polluting products thus have some monopsony power. So, it makes sense for these countries to introduce carbon tariffs first, and then for other importers to follow suit.

The logic of the carbon tariff under considerat­ion in the US is similar to that of the global minimum corporate income tax rate that G7 countries agreed on recently. Just as the proposed minimum rate aims to prevent tax avoidance by multinatio­nal corporatio­ns, Biden’s carbon tariffs would seek to prevent “greenwashi­ng” that could undermine the US and European shift to climate-smart growth.

In the EU’s plan and Biden’s thinking, carbon import duties would complement domestic carbon taxes or carbon credits, and help economies switch to greener growth. The EU has long aimed to establish itself as an internatio­nal climate leader. Likewise, a strong signal from the US that it intends to reduce trade-related CO2 emissions could be globally significan­t and help cement Biden’s growing reputation as a president who gets big things done.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus