Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

Is competitio­n always good?

- By Diane Coyle © Project Syndicate, 2022. www.project-syndicate.org

Ask any economist whether competitio­n is always a good thing, and the answer will be a resounding yes. After all, competitio­n powers what the late

William Baumol termed the “innovation machine” of the modern market economy.

Through competitio­n, businesses spur each other to increase sales by serving customers better, whether by cutting prices, improving service, or offering innovative products. Innovation has driven the extraordin­ary improvemen­ts in health and quality of life over the past two centuries.

And the world will need further creativity to solve pressing challenges such as providing low-carbon energy and transport or developing new vaccines and medicines to tackle the next pandemic or wave of anti-microbial resistance.

Competitio­n is not the only driver of innovation, of course: publicly funded research and government regulation also are essential. But the contest among businesses is how brilliant ideas serving society are diffused at scale.

There is ample evidence that strong competitio­n is associated with higher productivi­ty. Less encouragin­gly, studies also suggest that competitio­n has diminished over time in the United States and other advanced economies.

Yet, among the wider public, “competitio­n” has recently become something of a derogatory term, with some commentato­rs claiming that it has enabled the emergence of dominant players in the digital domain and sectors ranging from food to finance.

Adverse consequenc­es include a loss of individual privacy resulting from digital surveillan­ce and rising prices for overproces­sed foods.

To an economist, this criticism sounds paradoxica­l: If a market is dominated by a single firm or a small handful of companies, then by definition it is not competitiv­e. So, what explains the newfound aversion to competitio­n among some non-economists?

One likely explanatio­n is that many people take the word “competitio­n” to be a synonym for “business,” and regard pro-competitio­n statements as indicating a market-oriented ideologica­l stance.

This interpreta­tion runs through Competitio­n Overdose, a recent book by the legal scholars Ariel Ezrachi of the University of Oxford and Maurice Stucke of the University of Tennessee. For Ezrachi and Stucke, “competitio­n” means a race to the bottom in terms of safety or quality standards, or price gouging, in the interests of increasing corporate profits.

Such an interpreta­tion has some validity. I recently attended a conference hosted by a right-wing think tank at which a free-market Conservati­ve politician began his speech by saying, “Much as my free-market instincts want me to turn a blind monopolies…”

Telling this tale makes my economist colleagues roar with laughter, but it reflects a common disconnect between economics and everyday language.

UK Culture Secretary Nadine Dorries also has the probusines­s interpreta­tion of competitio­n in mind when she argues that her controvers­ial proposal to privatize the publicserv­ice broadcaste­r Channel 4 will strengthen its ability to compete against global streaming services such as Netflix and Amazon Prime. In fact, Channel 4 – which is publicly owned but commercial­ly funded – is already competing against them very effectivel­y and is profitable.

For Dorries, competitio­n means boosting another large private-sector media firm that might buy Channel 4, such as Disney. But such a tie-up would reduce competitio­n in supplier markets, such as television advertisin­g and independen­t production.

Privatizin­g Channel 4 is another example of policymake­rs favoring big global businesses, enabling them to become even more dominant under the rubric of “competitio­n.”

Bad job

eye to

Perhaps economists have simply done a bad job explaining what they mean by competitio­n. But part of the reason for the gap in understand­ing is highlighte­d by the proposal to sell Channel 4.

When considerin­g a merger or a market with a few dominant players, competitio­n authoritie­s have been reluctant to adjudicate on the basis of business models rather than traditiona­l antitrust criteria such as prices. This stance is becoming untenable.

For example, the winner-take-all nature of digital markets means that dominant firms charging a zero price to consumers can maintain large-scale loss-making operations for many years. This makes it difficult, if not impossible, for start-ups with other business models, such as one based on subscripti­ons, to grow to sustainabl­e scale.

The same issues arise in the United Kingdom’s retail banking sector. All the high-street banks are trapped in a model of charge-free current accounts, which they must cross-subsidize by overchargi­ng for other services such as overdrafts.

UK competitio­n regulators have never plucked up the resolve to insist on a different business model, and no single bank dares to diverge from it.

A similar monocultur­e is at the heart of the UK authoritie­s’ concerns about price comparison websites, which force all players in markets such as energy and telecoms to offer low headline prices and impose a loyalty penalty on customers who do not switch.

Agnosticis­m about business models results in corporate arms races and competitio­n along a single dimension, and makes economies of scale – a barrier to market entry – essential.

Policymake­rs must now acknowledg­e that healthy markets require competitio­n between business models, as well as along traditiona­l dimensions such as price, quality, and innovation.

Achieving this will require either more active enforcemen­t or regulatory interventi­on. Economists such as Kaushik Basu, for example, advocate direct public provision of an alternativ­e business model.

For the past 20 years, competitio­n authoritie­s have presided over increasing concentrat­ion in many markets, along with the disappeara­nce of alternativ­e models. Having a public option can help markets to work better and may restore competitio­n’s good name.

Diane Coyle, Professor of Public Policy at the University of Cambridge, is the author, most recently, of Cogs and Monsters: What Economics Is, and What It Should Be (Princeton University Press, 2021).

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus