Financial Mirror (Cyprus)

IMF needs to mitigate climate transition risk

- By Xiaobei He, Irene Monasterol­o and Kevin P. Gallagher

The latest scientific assessment by the Intergover­nmental Panel on Climate Change makes it abundantly clear that the costs of inaction on global warming are rising rapidly and will disproport­ionately fall on poorer countries that bear no responsibi­lity for causing the problem. But what is often overlooked is that climate action itself may also have unintended negative effects in the developing world.

Scholars and central bankers usually refer to two types of climate-related financial risk: “physical risks” and “transition risks.” Whereas physical risk is a result of increases in emissions concentrat­ion, transition risks can emerge from technologi­cal shocks and from the introducti­on of climate policies and regulation­s in key economies.

Between 1850 and 1990, the United States and Europe accounted for 75% of cumulative carbon dioxide emissions. Today, they contribute about 50%, whereas China, India, and other emerging economies account for a growing share. Given this history, the US and Europe must act boldly to address the climate problem, charting a path for the world’s fast-growing emitters to follow. Together, the US, the European Union, China, and India account for more than 55% of world GDP. As the leading drivers of global production and consumptio­n patterns, their actions tend to “spill over” to other countries.

Thus, suddenly introducin­g policies and regulation­s designed to phase out fossil fuels in one of these major economies could strand not only physical assets (like oil rigs) but also workers and communitie­s. Many other countries around the world could then face fiscal and financial instabilit­y.

Ambitious climate policies to replace fossil fuels with clean energy sources will benefit all only if they reduce these “transition spillover risks.” That will require coordinati­on among countries and significan­t investment­s in resilience, adaptation, and adjustment support for workers and entreprene­urs in the legacy fossil-fuel industries.

Transition spillover risks can occur whenever climate action in one country inflicts a negative shock on the balance of payments and public debt of a commercial partner that exports fossil fuels or highcarbon goods. Fortunatel­y, new research from the Task Force on Climate, Developmen­t, and the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund, of which we are members, seeks to fill this knowledge gap. In the task force’s first technical paper, we examine the implicatio­ns of the EU’s proposed Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism (CBAM).

In the upper bound of our estimates, we find that it would adversely affect exports and welfare in many developing countries.

For example, with the broadest implementa­tion of the CBAM, Mozambique’s economy could shrink by 2.5%, Russia’s by 0.6%, and India’s, Egypt’s, and Turkey’s by almost 0.3% each.

Thus, income and welfare inequality between rich and poor economies could worsen, further eroding some low-income countries’ capacity to decarboniz­e.

Another study examines how carbon pricing in China (consistent with the scenarios offered by the Network for Greening the Financial System) would affect Indonesia, an emerging market with strong trade links to the Chinese economy.

The authors conclude that a Chinese coal phaseout, by curtailing demand for Indonesian coal, would adversely affect Indonesia’s balance of payments, fiscal position, and public debt, owing to the stranding of assets in the mining sector, which plays a key role in the domestic economy. These findings are not an excuse for climate inaction. But they do underscore the need for more internatio­nal coordinati­on. Climate-change mitigation and adaptation must be pursued in a manner that is consistent with maintainin­g financial stability, achieving the Sustainabl­e Developmen­t Goals, and fostering equity within and across national borders.

As the only global, rules-based, multilater­al institutio­n charged with maintainin­g financial stability, the IMF should take the lead on managing transition spillover risks. As part of its global and bilateral surveillan­ce functions, it should help member states identify the sources of short- and longer-term risks.

And the IMF should work in tandem with the World Bank and other developmen­tfinance institutio­ns to help countries mobilize the external and domestic resources needed to decarboniz­e their economies while also maintainin­g fiscal and financial stability.

Even then, though, some countries will inevitably suffer unintended consequenc­es. In those cases, the IMF should avoid attaching onerous conditiona­lities to its financing programs, as such provisions have been shown to worsen poverty and inequality and hamper long-run growth.

A better option is to rely on new mechanisms such as the proposed Resilience and Sustainabi­lity Trust, which would provide short-term financing (without onerous conditions and at concession­al rates) to help address balance-of-payments and liquidity challenges from transition spillover risks. Alternativ­ely, an “Equitable Decarboniz­ation Fund” financed from CBAMs and domestic carbon taxes could also be used to support decarboniz­ation in fossilfuel source countries.

We are now in the important decade for addressing climate change. Future economic stability, growth, and human well-being may well depend on whether the IMF will step into its role as a global coordinato­r for climate policy.

Xiaobei He is Deputy Director of the Macro and Green Finance Lab at the National School of Developmen­t at Peking University. Irene Monasterol­o, Professor of Climate Finance at the EDHEC Business School and EDHEC-Risk Institute, is a visiting research fellow at the Boston University Global Developmen­t Policy Center. Kevin P. Gallagher is Professor of Global

Developmen­t Policy at Boston University and Director of the Boston University Global Developmen­t Policy Center.

 ?? ??
 ?? ??
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Cyprus