Aviation Ghana

Howard Davies on forward guidance, central-bank independen­ce, the Volcker Rule, and more

- By Howard Davies Howard Davies is Chairman of NatWest Group and former Deputy Governor of the Bank of England. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2022. www.project-syndicate.org

Howard Davies Says More…

Project Syndicate: In May 2021, you noted that, despite Brexit, the City of London would remain Europe’s largest financial marketplac­e, but its Golden Age as Europe’s financial capital was over. With Prime Minister Boris Johnson’s resignatio­n, the United Kingdom now confronts a new bout of political turmoil, compoundin­g post-Brexit uncertaint­y. How might this affect the fortunes of the City of London, and the UK economy more broadly?

Howard Davies: There is no chance that either of the remaining candidates – former Chancellor of the Exchequer Rishi Sunak and Foreign Secretary Liz Truss – will change the government’s policy on Brexit. Sunak is more familiar with the policy’s regulatory elements, and there are some potential changes that may help insurance companies and the capital markets. But regulatory cooperatio­n between the UK and the European Union – with which a memorandum of understand­ing has been negotiated but not signed – will remain blocked until the Northern Ireland issue is resolved. In the near term, London’s fortunes are in Belfast’s hands – an unusual state of affairs! PS: Not long after the US Federal Reserve implemente­d an interestra­te hike that ran counter to its previous guidance, European Central Bank President Christine Lagarde announced that the ECB would shift to a “meeting-bymeeting” approach to setting its policy rate. In January, you warned that “the costs of losing control of consumers’ inflation expectatio­ns, which the leading central banks appear to have done, could be high.” Does the ECB’s decision to abandon forward guidance aggravate or mitigate that risk? HD: The ECB is still playing catch-up, I fear. The history of central-bank forward guidance is short, and not at all sweet. The Bank of England tried it and failed under Mark Carney. The ECB’s experience has been similar: its guidance was rapidly overtaken by events. My concern now is that, since all three major western central banks were slow to react to inflationa­ry pressures, the cost of squeezing inflation out of the system will be quite high. PS: You recently examined the broader backlash against central bankers, arguing that monetary policymake­rs must address critics’ questions about the way monetary policy is conducted head-on. Is a rethink of centralban­k independen­ce and inflation targeting really in order? How can monetary policymake­rs best defend their reputation­s – and monetary stability – in the current environmen­t? HD: I would not want to see central-bank independen­ce fundamenta­lly changed, but there are signs that monetary policymake­rs have become hostages to “groupthink.” For example, three of the four external members of the BOE’s Monetary Policy Committee have been advocating faster interestra­te increases for some time, but Bank insiders have voted as a bloc against them. Central banks need to be more open to different ways of thinking. They also need to overhaul their forecastin­g, which has gone badly awry in the last two years. By the Way…

PS: In your new book, The Chancellor­s: Steering the British Economy in Crisis Times, you highlight mistakes made by the BOE, the Financial Services Authority (FSA), and the Treasury during the 2008 global financial crisis. Which mistakes hold the most salient lessons for the challenges the UK is facing today? HD: I have more sympathy than some for the UK authoritie­s’ actions during the global financial crisis. Perhaps that is because I have worked in all three key institutio­ns: the Treasury, the BOE, and the FSA. Nonetheles­s, I would argue that some critics fail to recognize the pressure such institutio­ns were under to make quick decisions under uncertain conditions. In retrospect, I think the scale of quantitati­ve easing will be remembered as a policy error, the long-term consequenc­es of which are only now emerging. The UK’s largely pointless restructur­ing of the regulatory authoritie­s was an overreacti­on, as were the “ring-fencing” rules, which drew artificial lines down the middle of highly integrated banks. The latter damaged the competitiv­eness of UK banks, as no other country imposed a similar division. The Volcker Rule – which bars banks from engaging in proprietar­y trading or investing in hedge funds or private equity funds – is a far more sensible solution to the “too-big-to-fail” problem. PS: While you disagree with some criticisms of the UK Treasury – such as that it is too influentia­l – you do raise questions in The Chancellor­s about its ability to face some of the major challenges of our time, from tackling climate change to ensuring the sustainabi­lity of public finances. What is hampering the Treasury’s ability to address such imperative­s? Where should the Treasury be updating its thinking, and where should it stand firm? HD: I accept the charge of being too sympatheti­c to the Treasury at times. Someone has to give Treasury officials some love! But there are certainly areas where they lack relevant skills. In 2008, it was in the financialm­arkets arena – and they ended up relying too much on the BOE and the FSA. Now, it is arguably concerning climate change that the Treasury is poorly equipped: a convention­al cost-benefit analysis might lead to inadequate action, because it does not price carbon properly or understand the full scope of the relevant externalit­ies. Nonetheles­s, the Treasury must retain a grip on the public finances at a time when spending pressures, particular­ly on health and social care, are ever-growing. The British public wants Northern European levels of social provision and US tax rates. The two are not compatible. PS: In writing your book, you conducted in-depth interviews with past Chancellor­s of the Exchequer and key senior officials. Was there a conversati­on that changed your perspectiv­e on a particular issue or topic?

HD: When I started writing The Chancellor­s, I expected to conclude that the UK Treasury was too big, and that we would be better served by two institutio­ns – an economy ministry and a finance ministry – in line with the typical continenta­l European model. A conversati­on with Gus O’Donnell, a former permanent secretary to the Treasury, changed my mind. O’Donnell pointed out that all the attempts over the last 60 years to cut the Treasury down to size had originated in 10 Downing Street, whose occupants typically came to resent the presence of a powerful nextdoor neighbor. Would it be right to downgrade the Chancellor? In a system like the UK’s – in which a prime minister with a large parliament­ary majority can behave like an elected dictator – that would result in a dangerous concentrat­ion of power in one terraced house. It is a powerful argument, and I was convinced.

Read More Anéantir (Annihilate) By Michel Houellebec­q

Unusually, this is a novel about a Treasury official: its protagonis­t, Paul Raison, is an adviser to a future French finance minister, a very thinly disguised representa­tion of Bruno Le Maire. Anéantir is filled with Houellebec­q’s characteri­stic misanthrop­y and gloom, but also has a (faintly) upbeat ending. No other novelist I know feels the pulse of our confused and confusing politics as sensitivel­y. Vladimir By Julia May Jonas This American campus novel explores wokeness and the #MeToo movement in a subtle yet provocativ­e way. The story is told from the perspectiv­e of a middle-aged woman whose husband is accused of interferin­g with students. She sticks with him, and explores sexual fantasies of her own. Vladimir is brilliantl­y written, though it does have a melodramat­ic conclusion, which could have been omitted. The Price of Time: The Real Story of Interest By Edward Chancellor Chancellor advances a provocativ­e attack on recent central-bank orthodoxy, arguing that zero or negative interest rates have caused more economic problems than they have solved. He takes a long view of the issue, beginning in Mesopotami­a, moving through religious debates about usury, and examining John Law’s illfated scheme to revolution­ize the finances of the French state. His current diagnosis is that ultra-low rates are responsibl­e for low growth, high debt, and a slowdown in productivi­ty gains. I cannot follow him on his whole intellectu­al journey, but the changes he proposes are never less than thought-provoking. By a PS Contributo­r My personal lockdown project was a book on the British Treasury since 1997, when Tony Blair gave the BOE its monetary-policy independen­ce. I track the Treasury’s response to the global financial crisis, the Scottish independen­ce challenge, Brexit, and the COVID-19 pandemic through interviews with Chancellor­s of the Exchequer, their key aides, and other officials, who explain what they were trying to achieve at the time. Now that some time has elapsed, we can assess their performanc­e, finding that their record is mixed, though perhaps not as bad as some critics make it out to be (until Brexit), and that, throughout this period, the Treasury has retained its preeminent status in government.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Ghana