Aviation Ghana

HowtoEnfor­ceClimateA­greements with Trade Measures

- By Scott Barrett , Noah Kaufman and Joseph E. Stiglitz

Casual observers of the recent United Nations Climate Change Conference in Dubai (COP28) can be forgiven for attributin­g high stakes to the event. “We are on the brink of a climate disaster, and this conference must mark a turning point,” UN Chief António Guterres warned during the proceeding­s. Then, when a final agreement was reached, Canadian Environmen­t Minister Steven Guilbeault hailed its “breakthrou­gh commitment­s on renewable energy, energy efficiency, and the transition away from fossil fuels.”

But the truth is that neither the contents of the Dubai agreement, nor what was left out of it, will have much impact on climate change. We have seen this movie many times before, starting with the 1992 treaty that created the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change. Back then, all countries committed to preventing “dangerous” climate change, which would have required dramatic cuts in annual global greenhouse­gas (GHG) emissions. But emissions have continued to rise, albeit at a lower rate than they might have otherwise. Voluntary commitment­s have proven mostly hollow.

To be clear, we are not suggesting that fevered warnings about climate risks and the need for action are misguided. As economists who have spent decades studying climate change, we recognize that some of the economics literature has too often been used by those opposing a meaningful response. As we note in a recent report for the Institute of Global Politics, economic models that purport to identify “optimal” climate policies often systematic­ally underestim­ate the benefits of emissions reductions and overestima­te their costs.

Moreover, economists have let their admiration for a single policy solution, carbon taxes, get the better of them. This has given rise to misleading claims that relying on carbon prices alone is the most cost-effective way to reduce emissions. In fact, the many market failures that stand in the way of a rapid, equitable transition to net-zero emissions underscore the need for a broad portfolio of policies (which includes carbon prices).

In a world of urgent challenges, policymake­rs and the public have limited attention for climate change. Rather than focusing so much on internatio­nal conference­s that require unanimous support, entail no accountabi­lity, and ultimately have little effect on emissions, we should be directing our energies toward negotiatin­g agreements that can achieve transforma­tional progress in narrow, but crucial, economic sectors.

We already know that this more targeted approach works. Consider the Montreal Protocol, which protects the stratosphe­ric ozone layer, or the Internatio­nal Convention for the Prevention of Pollution from Ships (MARPOL). Unlike the voluntary commitment­s made at each climate-change COP, these two treaties establishe­d binding obligation­s that can be enforced through internatio­nal trade markets. The Montreal Protocol bars participat­ing countries from

trading in chlorofluo­rocarbons (ozone-depleting chemicals) with non-participat­ing countries; and under MARPOL, access to ports is restricted to ships that meet certain technical standards.

These two treaties have worked because they create positive feedback effects: the more countries that agree to participat­e, the higher the pressure on others to join. As a result, the ozone layer will return to its pre-1980 level in a few decades, and over 99% of oil is now shipped according to MARPOL specificat­ions, virtually eliminatin­g a major source of marine pollution.

The same approach has already worked for climate agreements. The Kigali Amendment to the Montreal Protocol phases down hydrofluor­ocarbons, a powerful greenhouse gas. Like the examples above, the amendment incorporat­es a trade measure designed to create a positive feedback effect once a critical threshold of participat­ion has been met. Owing to this structure, ratificati­on is in every country’s interest. Even in polarized America, it received strong bipartisan support in the US Senate last year.

We should now do the same for other major emissions sources. Aluminum production, for example, is responsibl­e for about 2% of global GHG emissions each year. Yet by replacing carbon anodes with inert anodes, the industry could dramatical­ly reduce its emissions. An aluminum treaty might require that parties both switch to inert anodes and import aluminum only from other participat­ing parties.

In contrast to unilateral threats of trade measures, this approach to internatio­nal climate agreements is fundamenta­lly cooperativ­e and multilater­al. It differs from unilateral­ly imposing domestic regulation­s on foreign production, as the European Union is doing, or from imposing carbon-based tariffs on certain imports without any correspond­ing domestic regulation­s, as some in the US have proposed. These methods may only invite retaliatio­n.

To succeed, internatio­nal climate agreements must be compatible with countries’ economic strategies, not least those of lower-income countries like India, where most future emissions will occur. That is why the Montreal Protocol and Kigali Amendment include provisions whereby richer countries agree to help poorer countries pay the costs of compliance.

The internatio­nal community took the wrong lesson from the Kyoto Protocol. It should be obvious by now that relying on voluntary commitment­s and aspiration­al targets does not work. The problem with Kyoto was that it did not get the incentives right.

By focusing climate agreements on individual sectors, linking obligation­s to trade access, and addressing the “common but differenti­ated” roles of rich and poor countries in internatio­nal negotiatio­ns, the world will have a better chance to achieve the goals outlined in the Dubai agreement: a rapid and equitable transition to net-zero

emissions.

Then, future climate-change COPs can focus on other consequent­ial issues, rather than on crafting the right mix of hollow words that everyone can agree on.

Scott Barrett is the LenfestEar­th Institute Professor of Natural Resource Economics at Columbia University’s Climate School. Noah Kaufman, a senior research scholar at the Center on Global Energy Policy at Columbia’s School of Internatio­nal and Public Affairs, is a former senior economist for the Council of Economic Advisers and a former deputy associate director of energy and climate change at the White House Council on Environmen­tal Quality. Joseph E. Stiglitz, a former chief economist of the World Bank and former chair of the US President’s Council of Economic Advisers, is University Professor at Columbia University and a Nobel laureate in economics. © Project Syndicate 1995–2024

 ?? ??
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Ghana