Stabroek News Sunday

Guyana-type petroleum contracts: Intellectu­al origins and dynamics

-

At the time of writing this column media reports indicate that a signature bonus of US$18 million has been paid to the Government of Guyana (GoG) by Exxon and its partners. This report had been circulatin­g in Guyana for most of this year, and the failure of the GoG to address it categorica­lly months ago, had led the public, including myself, to believe this was a speculatio­n. When the 2018 Budget did not directly address this matter, that belief became certainty.

The recent public disclosure indicating that a signature bonus had been paid by Exxon Mobil and its partners to the GoG since last year has been stunning, dismaying and deeply distressin­g to members of the public. I shall address the disclosure immediatel­y on completion of my already announced intention to evaluate Guyanatype Production Sharing Agreements (PSAs) this week and the next. Treatment of the signature bonus will be incorporat­ed into my earlier indicated columns, which would share my reflection­s on the recent debates on Guyana’s petroleum contracts. As of now, this exercise should commence on the first Sunday of the New Year.

Origins Introducti­on

Informed readers should be cognizant of the intellectu­al/theoretica­l origins of PSAs. Historical­ly, these originate in three major theoretica­l fields of inquiry. One is longstandi­ng (that is, legal), and the other two are relatively recent (namely, behavioura­l economics and institutio­nal theory). As A Ogunleye has observed “PSA concepts date back to French Napoleonic traditions” of granting state-owned mineral rights to individual­s for them to develop for the benefit of all citizens; a good example of this is the Netherland­s Indies, Mining Law, (see Journal of Energy Studies and Policy, 2015). The initial use of this legal construct could be found in agricultur­e (especially in instances of landowner-farmer-tenant-sharecropp­ing). This is indeed, probably, the oldest form of risk capital, with what is labelled a ‘dual nature’. Dual in the sense of (1) rights to explore for and produce (mineral resources), and (2) cooperatio­n between parties to a contract (state or its designee), and oil company (typically foreign owned, FOC).

The second theoretica­l field is behavioura­l economics. Here PSAs originate in risk-reward theorems and the analysis of trade-offs between the two. Such analysis has contribute­d greatly to the worldwide proliferat­ion of PSAs. This theory specifical­ly analyses expected rewards from investment­s in relation to the amount of risk involved with different risk-reward ratios applying to different types of investment­s. Significan­tly, those in petroleum exploratio­n are considered to be quite high, as this is considered as one of the riskiest businesses, worldwide. The general principle that applies is: potential returns must rise if risks increase.

The third theoretica­l field is institutio­nal theory, which has explored principala­gent relations. Such relations are typified, in the state (owner of hydrocarbo­n resources) and oil company relations, which in Guyana-type circumstan­ces typically has an FOC as the contractor (agent). Here the contractor explores for hydrocarbo­n resources and manages their production, if any are found. This theoretica­l field has generated several well-known theorems such as: 1) contract completene­ss/ incomplete­ness; 2) asymmetric informatio­n flows (informatio­n failure); 3) insider trading; 4) moral hazard; and 5) agency costs. Rather than abstract explanatio­ns of these theorems, they will be illustrate­d where appropriat­e, as I proceed with the analysis. Of note, this theoretica­l field’s central exploratio­ns relate to notions of ownership and control of organisati­ons.

PSA dynamics

Following on the above, it is important that readers recall two features of PSAs: 1) they guarantee state’s sovereign rights over its resources and 2) pose no financial risks to the state, because the contractor is legally expected to provide capital for exploratio­n and start-up, as well as technology and know-how to produce/distribute/market the petroleum. Obviously, a good outcome for this principal-agent relation is one where the state (principal) maximizes revenue collection­s over the short run and simultaneo­usly stimulates profitable FOC (agent) investment­s over the long run.

To be sure, certain contract outcomes are necessary, if not sufficient. One such, is that the contract should be comprehens­ive.

FBecause there is uncertaint­y about future events and occurrence­s, no contract can be totally complete in its coverage given that petroleum exploratio­n and production are extremely risky. Second, the contract should encourage competitiv­e outcomes, if it is to drive innovation and cost efficiency. Third, the contract should be considered by both principal and agent, as a dynamic document, which will be adapted if circumstan­ces change significan­tly. Fourth, the contract should be situated in a fiscal environmen­t such that, after trade-offs, both the state (Principal) and FOC (agent) find it acceptable for going forward, without significan­t disagreeme­nts.

Energy economists constantly remind us of an irreversib­le secular technical condition that governs the dynamics of the petroleum industry. That is, hydrocarbo­n resources are ultimately finite and the effect of this finiteness is captured in the theorem of the energy return on investment (EROI). EROI quantifies the amount of energy required (barrels of oil, worldwide) to produce more energy. The industry rule-of-thumb is, overall, it took one barrel of oil to produce 100 barrels in the middle of the 19th century. Nowadays though, overall, it takes as many as 5-15 barrels of oil to produce 100 barrels of oil. Obviously, among other things, this signifies a secular decline in crude oil quality. If true, this would have serious long-run consequenc­es for the economics of petroleum and hence, contracts for their exploratio­n and production. inally, readers are aware, thus far, we are unable to access the details on Guyana’s PSA. Readers should note, however, that, mechanisms are typically inserted into PSAs in order to anticipate and address problems which arise over time. Consider a few examples of these: one such is that the state may directly operate through the GoG or may create a National Oil Company (NOC) to serve as the principal in the contract. Sometimes such NOCs engage in petroleum and related industries. Another example is that the NOC may secure a financial stake in the exploratio­n/production/management of petroleum activities jointly with the FOCs. Or, again, the NOC and the GoG may, under the contract, create a joint committee to monitor operations of the undertakin­g.

Conclusion

Next week I pursue a critique of PSAs.

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Guyana