Stabroek News

The roots of Brazil’s economic crisis

- Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2020. www.project-syndicate.org

SÃO PAULO/GENT– When the COVID-19 pandemic hit Brazil’s economy, the country’s per capita income was already in steady decline. It was 7% below its 2013 level in 2019, and further declines were expected in 2020. And yet not long ago, there was considerab­le optimism regarding the country’s economic prospects.

In 2012, shortly before the start of the economy’s decline, the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund’s Article IV assessment cited “a remarkable social transforma­tion in Brazil, underpinne­d by macroecono­mic stability and rising living standards.” The IMF projected 4-5% annual GDP growth from 2013 onwards, and financial institutio­ns and media outlets shared its optimism.

What happened? It’s not that Brazil doesn’t know how to grow. The Growth Commission identified Brazil as one of the few countries able to maintain high growth rates for more than 25 years after World War II. Between 1950 and 1980, its economy grew at an average annual rate of 7%, with double-digit manufactur­ing growth. By the end of that period, Brazil’s manufactur­ing sector was more advanced than those of South Korea or India in terms of product diversific­ation and sophistica­tion.

With significan­t government support, Brazil developed one of the world’s largest aeronautic­s industries. (The crown jewel of that effort, Embraer, is now a private company.) Successive government­s supported the developmen­t of local varieties of a wide range of agricultur­al products, challengin­g received wisdom regarding the

suitabilit­y of the country’s soil and climate. Brazil has since become one of the world’s largest food exporters. State-owned Petrobras, now one of the world’s largest oil and gas companies, is a technologi­cal leader in deepwater drilling and has transforme­d Brazil from a net importer of oil to a net exporter.

What, then, explains the country’s post-2013 decline? The convention­al answer is fiscal and quasi-fiscal profli

gacy.

Former president Dilma Rousseff spent her way to reelection in 2014, disregardi­ng the long-term consequenc­es for government coffers. Fiscal and monetary excesses preceded the 2014 election: delays in adjusting utility tariffs, an artificial­ly overvalued exchange rate, and politicall­y motivated credit expansion via state

owned banks. These policies widened the fiscal deficit, fueled inflationa­ry pressure, spooked foreign investors, and put public debt on a dangerous trajectory.

Soon after her victory, Rousseff changed course. Fiscal contractio­n, tariff adjustment­s, and higher interest rates triggered a decline in private investment and led to the current collapse in growth.

But this explanatio­n is far from complete. The causes of Brazil’s economic malaise run deeper than Rousseff’s time in office.

First, the country’s growth foundation­s have weakened since 1980 – investment has decreased sharply, imports and exports as a share of GDP have declined and manufactur­ing has plunged from a quarter of GDP to about 10%.

Moreover, investment in infrastruc­ture has declined to below-depreciati­on levels. With no industrial growth to absorb the labour power released from agricultur­e, and with formal labour highly taxed, the informal sector has dominated the labour market. Whereas Brazil’s per capita income was twice that of South Korea in 1980, it is now half. Optimistic forecasts by the IMF and others consistent­ly ignored such adverse structural trends.

Second, Brazil has been successful when implementi­ng its own policy solutions. It ended high inflation in 1994 through the “Plano Real,” a stabilizat­ion plan based on the insight that the inflation index itself could become the unit of account, and thus the basis for a stable currency. This unorthodox plan, which the IMF declined to support, brought inflation down to single digits without the growth slowdown that typically accompanie­s stabilizat­ion.

A few years later, Brazil resisted “dollarizat­ion” pressure from the IMF, the United States, and financial investors. Instead, it addressed the financial instabilit­y brought about by the 1997 East Asian crisis by introducin­g the “triad”: a commitment to primary fiscal surpluses (achieved through significan­t tax increases), a floating exchange rate, and centralban­k independen­ce with the sole objective of targeting inflation.

The triad was successful at containing inflation and stabilizin­g financial flows. But good policies seldom remain so forever.

Brazil succumbed to the comfort of rigid rules. Macroecono­mic policies were put on autopilot; any bout of inflation was met with interest-rate increases. With an open capital account, financial inflows grew. And the exchange rate was left to appreciate regardless of the consequenc­es for exports or the real economy.

The “triad” policies were maintained long after they had stopped being useful. Interest rates, the world’s highest in real terms, have sustained an overvalued exchange rate, undercut exports, and made interest payments on public debt (which otherwise would have been manageable) Brazil’s largest fiscal-expenditur­e item (up to 8% in recent years).

Then, during Rousseff’s second term, just as the commodity boom was ending, the government lowered utility subsidies, cut expenditur­e, and increased real interest rates to several times the economy’s growth rate. Economic contractio­n accelerate­d and unemployme­nt increased. After Rousseff’s impeachmen­t in 2016, the government reinforced expenditur­e cuts, again without a growth strategy. Declines in GDP meant lower tax revenues and increased public debt.

Applauded by the IMF, the World Bank, and the internatio­nal and domestic financial press, the authoritie­s persisted with austerity, persuaded that fiscal contractio­n was expansiona­ry, even in the midst of a recession, because, by reducing expected future taxation, it would encourage entreprene­urs to increase their present investment­s. But it is counterint­uitive to expect entreprene­urs with existing idle capacity to expand such capacity even further.

Rousseff may have worsened Brazil’s economic travails during her 2014 presidenti­al campaign, and they have certainly been exacerbate­d by COVID-19. But neither is responsibl­e for Brazil’s weakened growth foundation­s, the lack of a developmen­t strategy, imprudent “imported” policy ideas, and rigid macroecono­mic rules. Addressing these shortcomin­gs will be the key to long-term prosperity.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Guyana