Business Standard

Stop the ongoing real estate monetisati­on scheme

- HARSH ROONGTA The writer is a registered investment advisor.

My grandfathe­r used to tell me about the abundant availabili­ty of rental housing in Mumbai, though at high levels during the time (probably the 1930s) when he first started working in the city, then Bombay. To save on rent he used to surrender the premises to the owner when he took his annual vacation back to our ancestral village in Rajasthan every summer, as he always got back either the same premises or in the same building or area. Retail home loans were unheard of and only rich businessme­n or trusts floated by them owned buildings. Everybody else stayed on rental premises. The party lasted till the Second World War, when the Rent Control Act first came in (and stayed on as an unwelcome guest till now). Real estate rental yields were never the same again. The capital gains on real estate in those days were never high anyway and the absence of loan availabili­ty ensured the common man did not have the ability or incentive to purchase his own home. The government­s wanted to encourage investment in real estate because of its known positive impact on the overall economy.

The way yields and capital gains on real residences were taxed reflected this scenario. The Income Tax Act 1922 (the precursor to the current Income Tax Act 1961) taxed rental incomes (including deemed rental income on self-occupied properties). Obviously there was no concept of a “loss” arising from the property. The Act of 1961 introduced the concept of capital gains tax for the first time. To encourage investment in real estate, it had a number of measures which can only be referred to as the real estate monetisati­on scheme (on the lines of the proposed gold monetisati­on scheme) which was immensely successful. Section 54 exempted the capital gains on residentia­l houses if it was rolled over into another house property. Section 54F was introduced in 1982 to encourage transfer from other asset classes into real estate. It was further liberalise­d in 2000 to allow even existing property owners to participat­e in the bonanza. The tax breaks were ongoing, since “loss from house property” is allowed to be adjusted against other incomes, including salaries and business. Given the low rental yield and then the increasing use of loans to purchase houses, the calculatio­n invariably resulted in a loss, which gave an excellent tax break to the owners. The common man buying a house for own use was fobbed off by making the deemed rental income nil and interest deduction up to ~30,000. Over a period of time this has increased to ~2,00,000.

To summarise this is how the tax structure looks. For common people who only ever hold one residentia­l property, the deduction for interest is restricted to a maximum loan of around ~20,00,000 and the capital gain relief on sale is meaningles­s since he anyway will buy a new house to stay in. Meanwhile, the investor enjoys the estate monetisati­on. First, the purchase of property acts as a store of black money and the white portion is funded by easily available loans. The rental yield being low does not matter, as he is able to get substantia­l benefit from the “loss” he incurs. On sale of the property, he obviously rolls it over into another property, thereby legitimisi­ng the original unaccounte­d money he invested plus, he gets opportunit­y to invest further unaccounte­d money that he may have generated in the meanwhile. Those holding other asset classes are also encouraged to get into this bandwagon by Section 54F. The Income tax act is designed to favour the laundering of black money through real estate and also to keep that money locked into real estate.

The obvious thing to correct this would be to:

1) Allow full deduction for interest payable if the self- occupied property is the only one owned by the tax payer.

2) Don’t allow the loss under income from house property to be set off against other heads of income. It can be carried forward and set off against future income from house property, if any

3) All capital gains exemption on investment in residentia­l property to be available only if the property purchased is the only property owned by the tax payer.

I don’t have access to data but I am reasonably sure these changes will result in overall higher tax collection for the government, make the common man happy and disincenti­vise the holding of unaccounte­d money in real estate.

If the government really wants to boost the householde­rs’ investment in financial assets, it should bring back Section 54E (discontinu­ed in 1992) whereby the capital gains were exempt if invested into specified financial assets. But despite all the lip service to promoting investment­s in financial assets, that would probably be too much to hope for.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India