Business Standard

Towards sustainabl­e urbanisati­on in China

- LU MING

China has received enormous dividends from its decades of urbanisati­on, which provided labour resources for the developmen­t of its industrial and service sectors and rapidly raised the income of the Chinese people. A large number of Chinese farmers became part of the country’s modernisat­ion process, facilitati­ng poverty alleviatio­n in rural areas. At the end of 2016, the urbanisati­on rate of China stood at around 57 per cent.

China however continues to face serious impediment­s in the urbanisati­on process.

One of these is the country’s household registrati­on system or the hukou, which connects a person’s right to access public services with whether or not he has a resident status in a locality. The reality is that some one-third of city dwellers in China are trans-regional immigrants who actually do not possess local household registrati­on. As a result, they do not enjoy the same level of social security and public services as local urban residents.

This is a particular­ly serious social problem for China. One major consequenc­e of linking the hukou to public service is that there exists 60 million liushouert­ong, or children left behind by their migrant parents in their home villages in China. These children are more or less left to fend for themselves and meet their parents only sporadical­ly over a year. At the same time, there are about 30 million migrant children in China’s cities who also do not enjoy the same education opportunit­ies as local urban children with the hukou.

The difficulty of educating these 100 million children is a chronic malady of the urbanisati­on process in China today. If not addressed, this problem poses a great threat to the healthy and sustainabl­e developmen­t of China’s economy in future.

China’s system of land allocation is another big barrier to urbanisati­on. The government controls the quantity of agricultur­al land that can be converted to urban land under a “constructi­on land index system”. As a result, the supply of newly added land is very limited and in cities such as Shanghai and Beijing, house prices are extremely high.

At the same time, the government provides greater allocation­s under the constructi­on land index to those areas which see a large population outflow, so as to help them develop local industries and build up new cities. While the intention is to retain the population, in reality, a large number of industrial parks are idle and new cities remain empty.

These problems are closely related to two popular but erroneous ideas in China. The first is that the population in Beijing and Shanghai is too high; the other is that it is the concentrat­ion of economic developmen­t only in the coastal areas and super large cities that leads to unequal economic developmen­t between regions.

In reality however, Beijing and Shanghai are more than just cities — they are metropolit­an areas composed of a number of cities around the central city. They have an area of about 16,000 sq km and 6,000 sq km, respective­ly, and can be compared to the Tokyo metropolit­an area. However, while the latter had a population of 37 million-plus at the end of 2015, the population of Beijing and Shanghai stood considerab­ly lower at 21.75 million and 24.15 million respective­ly. Even including the small cities nearby, Beijing and Shanghai lag behind Tokyo.

Meanwhile, in terms of regional imbalance, the problem is not overcentra­lisation of economic activity. There is, in fact, a lot of evidence to prove that China’s economic agglomerat­ion is far lower than that of developed countries and lower than some developing countries at a similar stage of developmen­t. The real problem is that the distributi­on of the population is not in tandem with the economy’s requiremen­ts, leading to the widening gap in the per capita GDP of different regions.

The solution to the problem is not to seek greater evenness in regional economic distributi­on but to let the population move still more freely. This would allow each region’s GDP to accord more naturally with whatever its share of the population is.

In practice, however, China’s household registrati­on system and discrimina­tory public services system have become ways to limit population in the mega cities. The government also uses administra­tive power to transfer resources to the less developed regions in order to balance regional developmen­t. After 2003, the land supply to the in-flow areas was tight while land supply was eased in the out-flow areas. As a result, house prices in some first-tier cities reached astonishin­gly high levels while a large number of thirdand fourth-tier cities have turned into ghost cities.

The Chinese government purports to respect the laws of urban developmen­t, but Chinese society itself is not educated about the laws of urban developmen­t. Only by realising the prevailing laws of urbanisati­on — that the rate of urbanisati­on will constantly move upward and that the population will naturally concentrat­e in big cities — can resource allocation during urbanisati­on adhere to market principles. The Chinese government needs to increase the supply of land as well as public services and infrastruc­ture availabili­ty to all residents in in-flow areas, to ensure that China’s urbanisati­on follows a healthy and sustainabl­e trend in the future.

One-third of China’s city dwellers are trans-regional immigrants who do not possess local household registrati­on. They therefore do not enjoy the same level of public services as local urban residents

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India