Business Standard

THE OTHER SIDE

- A V RAJWADE

In my post-Budget article (“Cover the full ground”, February 8), I had argued that a full reform of government accounts on both flow and stock bases is necessary, and that it will be interestin­g to see what the panel reviewing the Fiscal Responsibi­lity and Budget Management Act says about it. The panel’s report is now in public domain. To me, two major lacunae in the report are:

Silence about the adoption of the Internatio­nal Public Sector (that is, government) Accounting Standards recommendi­ng full disclosure of all assets, liabilitie­s and contingent liabilitie­s, which is vital for assessing the true economic implicatio­ns of public sector financial management;

The cross-country data it uses gives a totally different picture than that quoted in the pre-Budget Economic Review.

As for the first, the issue of contingent liabilitie­s, legal or substantiv­e, is all the more important for us, given the various funds being floated to finance infrastruc­ture. To list a few: the $5-billion Railways of India Developmen­t Fund; the National Investment and Infrastruc­ture Fund; the Long-term Irrigation Fund. In times of difficulty, such off-balance-sheet liabilitie­s come back to the promoter: Remember the fate of the special investment vehicles of commercial banks in the US, and the “privately owned” housing loans refinance institutio­ns in that country, at the time of the 2008 financial crisis?

This apart, let me turn to a couple of important points in the report. The first is the arithmetic of the way the deficit targets up to 2023 have been arrived at, and their implicatio­ns. The objective is to reduce the public debt level (Centre and states together) to 60 per cent of nominal gross domestic product (GDP) from the current level of 70 per cent. Of this, the share of states is to remain at 20 per cent, with that of the Centre being brought down to 40 per cent. This will require the fiscal deficit to come down to 2.5 per cent in stages by 2023, that is, over six years. The assumed nominal GDP growth is 11.5 per cent per annum.

For arriving at the deficit target, the report relies on the logic that “net household financial savings were reported at 7.6 per cent of GDP in FY15. Further, India’s external borrowing needs, proxied by its sustainabl­e current deficit in the medium term, are estimated at roughly 2.3 per cent of GDP. Therefore, a total of around 10 per cent of GDP of household savings and external borrowing would be available for the public and private sectors in the medium term, which the committee assumed to be allocated equally between the two. This would lead to a combined fiscal deficit of the Centre and the states of five per cent of GDP, and at the same time ensure an investment of five per cent of GDP. The five per cent general government deficit, divided equally between the Centre and the states, would imply a 2.5 per cent deficit for the Centre in the medium term”.

The logic raises several issues. Is the level of household savings a “given”? Surely, it depends on several tangible and intangible variables — the real interest and exchange rates, the “animal spirits” of the consumer, etc. Again, is a current account deficit of 2.3 per cent of GDP “sustainabl­e” year after year? As it is, our net internatio­nal investment position is a negative $360 billion. Adding 2.3 per cent of GDP to it each year will take it to, say, $650 billion plus by 2023. Will the rest of the world finance our excess consumptio­n forever? Or, at some stage, will there be capital flight and a balance of payments crisis? And, is 7.5 per cent real growth sustainabl­e despite the output loss implicit in the external deficit? Has any economy grown at that rate year after year except through surpluses on the external account — from Japan during its miracle years, to Korea, to Taiwan, to China? What we need is rapid growth in manufactur­ing to create jobs — and that is unlikely to come through external deficits.

Another issue is how an ever lower fiscal deficit will provide finance for needed infrastruc­ture investment, except through “creative accounting” like off-balance-sheet funds, and/or passing on the burden to commercial banks. We are seeing the effects of the latter — and of an uncompetit­ive exchange rate — in the asset quality of the banking system. Coming back to public debt, hardly any country has defaulted on domestic currency debt — but several have on external liabilitie­s, resulting from persistent current account deficits. We perhaps need a limit on the internatio­nal investment position far more than on public debt.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India