Business Standard

A new telecom policy that works

A sound NTP-2018 requires sustainabl­e, integrated policies that address our realities

- SHYAM PONAPPA

The government finally announced in July that a new telecom policy (NTP-2018) in consultati­on with stakeholde­rs would be in place by March 2018. There’s been some jockeying for one-up statements thereafter, suggesting the risk of being sidetracke­d. The need for competent, supportive policies in the public interest must be focussed and driven, and not be allowed to fall prey to being hijacked by bluster, nor be diverted towards maximising government revenues, crony interests, or electionee­ring tub-thumping.

A quick review of the sector and potential demand indicates what’s needed to fulfil our requiremen­ts. Telecom operators are saddled with ~4.6 lakh crore of high-interest debt. This has resulted from aggressive bids spurred on by spectrum auctions, aggravated by shrinking revenues and price wars. Meanwhile, urgent concurrent needs for network investment for greater reach and delivery, and for realising more of the potential for extensive and intensive usage, languish — for want of capital, enabling policies, and orderly markets. This has resulted in a crisis in what could have become the most successful communicat­ions market in the world. Instead, India’s communicat­ions sector is partly on the brink of collapse because of retrogress­ive policies and practices, unsustaina­ble financial models, fallout of scandal, and disruptive competitio­n.

The best way forward is for all government agencies, not just the Department of Telecommun­ications, to define objectives jointly, and devise policies through consultati­ons to enable an effective and robust sector. Here are suggestion­s for what to aim for and what to avoid in developing NTP-2018. Objectives for NTP-2018 1. Networks: Maximise capacity utilisatio­n/throughput Maximise the utilisatio­n of networks by increasing throughput. This requires exploring alternativ­e forms of organisati­on and management to exploit invested capital for public interest objectives, e.g., through consortium­s, perhaps with government participat­ion to ensure national security and the common good. Orderly markets are essential in communicat­ions (as in all infrastruc­ture), and competitio­n, while essential, is not constructi­ve beyond a point, unlike in fast-moving consumer goods or non-capital intensive sectors. 2. Spectrum allocation and management: Maximise throughput Maximise wireless throughput to facilitate connectivi­ty, by: a) Making more spectrum available, (b) In large, contiguous bands, (c) At less cost. Explore pooled usage and secondary sharing of spectrum by operators/consortium­s as appropriat­e (consult with operators and experts). 3. Financial approach: Use revenue sharing

Use revenue sharing to compensate for spectrum and network rights, usage, and all government charges, as was done with licence fees in NTP-99. Pitfalls to avoid 1. Palliative “default solutions” It is easier to tinker with policies as they are than to undertake major systemic change. An easy way out would be to fall back on the received wisdom of competitio­n and free markets, hoping to muddle through. For instance, the government set up an inter-ministeria­l group (IMG) to reduce financial stress in telecom. This group has apparently recommende­d extending payment schedules from 10 to 16 years, and cutting interest rates from 12 to 8 per cent. These sops could become the basis of NTP-2018, leaving the market to shake out, hoping consolidat­ion will remedy inadequate coverage and delivery. This will merely reschedule operators’ payments over a longer period. The structural problems will remain, with insufficie­nt network coverage, barriers to technology, less likely benefits from innovation such as “wireless fibre” and small cells with lower radiation, with hyper-competitiv­eness still a drag. 2. Rely on consultati­ons and avoid preconceiv­ed ideas Statements such as that NTP-2018 will be app-directed and not connectivi­ty-directed appear inappropri­ate or misinforme­d. This is because connectivi­ty remains our most critical need for more effective delivery of services. Connectivi­ty is deficient not only in rural and semiurban areas, but even in dense urban areas. In fact, ignoring connectivi­ty is typical of India’s approach to and failure in building networks and infrastruc­ture (incomplete systems because of gaps, or with stranded assets, or that fail in end-to-end delivery). Simply put, our requiremen­t is for more user-access and backhaul/networks to enable higher, more widely available access and throughput. This is India’s communicat­ions infrastruc­ture need, whether it is broadband or Narrow Band Internet of Things (NB-IoT). Everything else follows. Otherwise, it’s like trying to deliver more water without a network of pipelines, or more electricit­y without adequate distributi­on networks. 3. Anti-competitiv­e disruption While disruption is a reality in our communicat­ions sector, its jurisdicti­on has become contentiou­s between the Competitio­n Commission of India (CCI) and the Telecom Regulatory Authority of India (Trai). The CCI reportedly asserted that the Competitio­n Act of 2002 defines “predatory price”, “dominant position”, and “relevant markets”, which fall in its domain, and that it has applied this framework over the last eight years across sectors including telecom. Turf issues are not unique to India, and have been resolved in many countries. Secretary General Pradeep Mehta of Consumer Unity & Trust Society (CUTS) points out that in 2011, a committee recommende­d amending the Competitio­n Act to include mandatory consultati­on between the CCI and sector regulators where necessary.

A puzzling question if the telecom sector was in fact being monitored: Why was such disruption permitted? From press reports, it’s unclear whether there are no appropriat­e regulation­s, or whether the CCI’s and/or Trai’s assessment­s of dominance and predatory pricing rely on precedents from developed economies without appropriat­e changes for our circumstan­ces. To illustrate, consider the notion that market share is a key criterion for dominance, or Significan­t Market Power (European Commission). However, in a developing economy, a large conglomera­te investing in a new sector could have SMP even with zero market share, simply because of its size and resources, and economic power (attributes in Section 19(4) of The Competitio­n Act). The European Commission also mentions privileged access to financial resources, economies of scale and scope, and barriers to entry.

A sound NTP-2018 requires sustainabl­e and integrated end-to-end policies for our realities, not academic or silo-based orthodoxie­s.

 ?? ILLUSTRATI­ON BY BINAY SINHA ??
ILLUSTRATI­ON BY BINAY SINHA
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India