Business Standard

Alarmists must not derail policy direction

Government­s in almost all market economy countries intervene to a greater or a smaller degree in their industries. India, finally, might be on the same path

- SANTOSH MEHROTRA

India’s Budget 2018, which raised customs duties on many imported manufactur­es, finally suggests that the government recognises the need for (a) an industrial policy; and (b) a trade policy that complement­s the first. However, mainstream economists/journalist­s are a a-flutter as they believe India is abandoning economic reforms (Panagariya, 12 February 2018, “Return of protection­ism”). This is strange, to say the least.

Government­s in almost all market economy countries intervene to a greater or a smaller degree in their industries. The US government intervenes in industry through anti trust laws, industrial standards, pollution regulation­s, and labor laws. However, no one would contend the US has an “industrial policy”, but Japan did and East Asian countries do. What makes interventi­ons by East Asian (Japan, South Korea, Taiwan)/other South-East Asian countries into an “industrial policy” is that their interventi­ons were generally coordinate­d and viewed as a coherent whole. India, finally, might be on the same path.

Equally, in all East/SE Asian countries, industrial policy was executed as part of five year or longer-term plans. In fact, it was precisely because these countries had planning institutio­ns — which went hand in hand with industrial policy — that they managed to steer policies through good and turbulent times in the global economy, sustaining growth. They did not, unlike much of Latin America (LAC) or Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), experience “lost decades” in the 1980s-90s.

By contrast, in LAC and SSA two decades of potential economic growth were lost, hence per capita income barely rose, just when their population­s were rising. This was not the case in East/SE Asia, which grew rapidly but also transforme­d their structure of output/employment, ensuring major achievemen­ts in human developmen­t. The important identifier of these East/SE Asian countries were their planning structures, backed by effective industrial policy, implemente­d by learning bureaucrac­ies.

However, many were sceptical that industrial policy could be practiced in other developing countries, since they have weaker bureaucrac­ies and that, the internatio­nal community today is unlikely to accept interventi­onist industrial and trade policies. So dominant was this mode of thinking when India launched economic reforms, that Indian policy-makers seem to have fallen prey to it as well. While the 1991 economic reforms were exactly the right response to the irrational and distortion­ary dirigisme prevailing until the early 1980s, it took two decades (2011) before a National Manufactur­ing Policy was announced (which never got to implementa­tion stage); the National Electronic­s Design & Manufactur­ing, 2012, remained confined to paper.

Since 1991 the implicit policy seems to have been: reduce high tariffs, deregulate domestic markets, end industrial licencing and market forces will ensure that manufactur­ing investment will thrive. However, the share of manufactur­ing in neither output nor employment increased grew since in 1991; it was and is 16 per cent of GDP and under 12 per cent of employment. Manufactur­ing has in 25 years not been the lead sector. Services have driven growth. Unfortunat­ely India saw premature growth of services, without accompanyi­ng manufactur­ing growth, that was the well-establishe­d Kuznets pattern. Services, especially traditiona­l ones (for example, wholesale/retail trade, transport, domestic services) became the receptacle for absorbing surplus labour from rural areas.

However, time is more than ripe now for this policy path dependence to change. India still does not have an industrial policy (that DIPP began consultati­ons towards one is a good beginning, and a recognitio­n that we don’t have one). Improving ease of doing business is an integral element of one, but it is only an element. Recognisin­g that logistics is a especially difficult Indian constraint on all sectors, not just manufactur­ing, and hence creating a new unit for logistics in the DIPP is a good idea; but this is also only just another element. Every government has invested in better infrastruc­ture, which is a critical element of better logistics support.

However, industrial policy should have several components (on which more later). But first, recognisin­g that India’s ballooning trade deficit with China is accounted for by exports of manufactur­es to India is critical to policy correction­s. Also, policy should note import-intensity of Indian manufactur­ing production has systematic­ally risen. This partly contribute­d to rising exports of manufactur­es, which had imported inputs. However, within manufactur­ing the average trade-ratio has risen sharply over 20 years. Moreover, capital intensity of manufactur­es rose. Also, the capital- and skill-intensity of exports rose. The result: jobs in manufactur­ing fell between 2005 and 2010, and although they rose till 2012, they have since fallen in absolute terms again.

Yet Panagariya has no hesitation in sounding the alarm (on the Budget slightly raising tariffs on manufactur­es): “For those of us old enough to remember the India of the 1960s to the 1980s, this is déjà vu. Thanks to ultra-high protection and tight internal regulation, India was condemned to per capita growth of less than 2 per cent during 1950 and 1990”. What alarmists forget is that tariffs in 1990 stood at an average rate of 150 per cent. Reduction from 1991 to 1998 was precipitou­s, to an average of 40 per cent by 1999, and to 10 per cent in 2007-8. Indian manufactur­ers unreasonab­ly protected till 1990 were too quickly exposed to competitio­n. A slower reduction would have enabled them to adjust to import competitio­n and upgrade technology. All that Budget 2018 does is to raise rates to 20-25 per cent at best in a limited number of manufactur­es. A more comprehens­ive reexaminat­ion is now necessary.

Even the limited reversal of inverted duty structures in electronic­s since 2014 has resulted in domestic inputs into electronic­s rising, even though all integrated circuits still come from China. We also know that within the last decade the Indian auto sector output has risen sharply, making automobile­s’ share in manufactur­ing value added as high as 49 per cent. This sector did not suffer from an inverted duty structure.

Alarmists must not be allowed to derail the policy direction.

The author is a professor of economics, JNU, and Chair of the Centre for Labour. santoshmeh@gmail.com

 ??  ??
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India