Business Standard

Great thinkers and the 2008 crisis

- ISHAN BAKSHI

In the aftermath of the global financial crisis of 2008, there has been much soul searching among economists over why most of them failed to predict it. Since then, many books have attempted to trace the history of economic thought hoping to find answers to our current predicamen­t.

One such attempt was that of Professor Meghnad Desai. In Hubris, Mr Desai traced the history of economic thought through the ages as he attempted to answer a simple question: Why did economists fail to foresee the crisis of 2008 that threatened to take down the world economy?

In a similar vein, in a new book, titled The Great Economists: How Their Ideas Can Help Us Today, Linda Yueh, a Fellow in Economics at St Edmund Hall, University of Oxford, explores the works of some of the most notable figures in the profession.

The author says the economists who have made the cut are those whose theories have changed the world and whose ideas can help with today’s challenges, so the list is hardly a novel one. All the giants in the profession — from Adam Smith to Karl Marx to John Maynard Keynes to Milton Friedman — are featured, and they are economists whose ideas have been discussed threadbare and perhaps with greater rigour than Ms Yueh’s treatment.

The book is lucidly written, however, with each chapter devoted to the life and work of these towering giants and to the social milieu that shaped their thinking. It offers glimpses into the lives of these influentia­l economists, often laced with interestin­g nuggets of informatio­n.

The burden of the book is to examine how these economists would view the world of today — how they would have reacted to the policies adopted by government­s and central banks to deal with the crisis of 2008. Perhaps a more interestin­g method would have been to pit two economists on either side of the debate.

Consider for example the role of fiscal policy.

Friedrich Hayek, the eminent Austrian economist, disputed the use of fiscal policy in moderating the business cycle. He believed that government­s should simply resist the urge to interfere in the economy — a view diametrica­lly opposite to that held by Keynes.

Hayek viewed recessions as necessary evils. As Ms Yueh points out, for him, recessions were periods of liquidatio­n that resulted from the past over-accumulati­on of capital. He argued that any policy that would stimulate the economy would perhaps reduce some short-term suffering, but would “ultimately prevent recovery by helping maintain inefficien­t capital stock levels”.

Keynes, on the other hand, was in favour of government spending during crisis. As Ms Yueh notes, he argued that there would not be any crowding out of private investment when the economy is operating below its potential.

Take the case of the British economy. It had lost over 6 per cent of its output during the recession of 2008. In such a scenario, Ms Yueh believes that Keynes would have argued that crowding out was unlikely as “there was enough scope for public and private sectors to invest before demand for funds pushed up borrowing costs”. However, contrary to what Keynes might have advocated, the British government initially swerved right, imposing stiff austerity measures.

Hayek also believed that misallocat­ion of capital could be a consequenc­e of monetary policy as well, specifical­ly if interest rates were kept too low. In fact, as Ms Yueh points out, he had argued that the US Federal Reserve had actually played a role in precipitat­ing the great depression by keeping interest rates too low through the 1920s.

Fast-forward to the 2000s and perhaps Hayek would have argued that a similar situation existed. The US Federal Reserve had cut rates to record lows which many have argued facilitate­d the build-up in the real estate market. Ms Yueh argues that Hayek would not have been opposed to the liquidatio­n of Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, in principle, but he would have strongly opposed the policy of quantitati­ve easing adopted by the Fed to inject liquidity into the system. This view would place him in direct opposition to Milton Friedman.

In their seminal work, Friedman and Anna J Schwartz had argued that the Great Depression was essentiall­y a liquidity problem. Friedman’s approach to tackle such episodes was to simply flood the economy with liquidity and “allow solvency issues to sort themselves out”.

Since he had been supportive of the Bank of Japan’s quantitati­ve easing, Ms Yueh argues that he might have viewed the US Fed’s unconventi­onal policies as necessary to get lending going again. Thus, he would have approved the vast amount of purchases of US government debt by the Fed to keep long-term interest rates down, though he might have viewed the purchase of mortgageba­cked securities as a bailout.

On bailouts, though, he might have taken a different stance. Ms Yueh contends that Friedman might have viewed the targeted interventi­ons by the Fed to save Bear Stearns and AIG but to allow Lehman Brothers to go under as underminin­g the institutio­n’s independen­ce and credibilit­y.

THE GREAT ECONOMISTS

How their ideas can help us today Linda Yueh

Viking (Penguin)

357 pages; ~699

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India