Business Standard

Challengin­g the monopolies

-

The antitrust movement is making a comeback. Zephyr Teachout, candidate for New York state attorney general, is promising to fight monopolies. Activists such as Matt Stoller of the Open Market Institute are beginning to draw attention to the problem of concentrat­ed market power. Think tanks like the Washington Center for Equitable Growth are starting to zero in on the issue as well. The revival of this movement is still in its infancy, and certainly hasn’t reached anything approachin­g the fervour of the Progressiv­e Era a century ago. But the new antitrust crusaders are experienci­ng a tailwind from an unlikely ally — the economics profession.

In the past, economists have not exactly crowned themselves with glory in the fight to keep big business from getting too big. Some have made a bomb of money offering their services as consultant­s to companies looking to execute megamerger­s. The so-called Chicago School of antitrust analysis, popularise­d during the mid-20th century, dismissed the dangers of market concentrat­ion except in the case of explicit price-fixing or outright domination of a market by a single company. This school of thought heavily influenced the burgeoning movement to integrate law and economics, leading to looser antitrust enforcemen­t in the 1980s and afterwards.

But in the past few years, economists have become increasing­ly concerned with the problem of stagnating wages. Profits have grown strongly since the turn of the century, but real wages — even including health and retirement benefits — have risen only slightly.

There are many theories to explain the divergence: Global (especially Chinese) competitio­n, the impact of technology, and rising land values. But another theory — rising market power — is gaining increasing currency in the profession.

In the past few years, a series of papers by a mix of younger and well-establishe­d economists has argued that industry is becoming more concentrat­ed, partly as a result of mergers; that this concentrat­ion has led to higher consumer prices and lower wages; and that companies are managing to squeeze more profit out of the economy even as they invest less for the future.

Now the concern about monopoly power is spilling out beyond the halls of academia, and reaching the ears of the country’s top policymake­rs. At the recent Jackson Hole, Wyoming, policy conference, central bankers from the Federal Reserve heard a number of senior figures sound the alarm. Those included Esther George, the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Massachuse­tts Institute of Technology economist John Van Reenen, and Jason Furman and Alan Krueger, two Ivy League professors and former economic advisers to the Barack Obama administra­tion.

Krueger’s remarks provide a good overview of the emerging consensus. He notes that even as industries have become more concentrat­ed, the traditiona­l forces that balance the power of corporatio­ns have weakened: The decline in union representa­tion and the erosion of the real value of the minimum wage have contribute­d to the significan­t rise in inequality and polarisati­on of incomes in the US since the early 1980s.

Krueger also notes that structural changes in the US economy — the rise of noncompete agreements, temp-staffing agencies and outsourcin­g — have aggravated the situation.

Meanwhile, the steady drumbeat of research papers continues. A paper by economists Chris Edmond, Virgiliu Midrigan and Daniel Yi Xu built a model showing how high markups -- the difference between the price a company charges for its products and the cost it paid to create those products — can be very detrimenta­l to consumers. Van Reenen, with co-authors Zack Cooper, Stuart Craig and Martin Gaynor, connects monopoly power to health-care prices — the authors looked at price variation in health-care markets and found that in places where hospitals have a local monopoly, prices are 12 per cent higher. Ioana Marinescu and Herbert Hovenkamp discuss the possibilit­y of using antitrust law to prevent companies from lowering wages, rather than maintainin­g the current exclusive focus on consumer prices.

It’s important to note that the economics profession isn’t in universal agreement about the issue. A team of researcher­s from the Economic Policy Institute has argued that rising market concentrat­ion can explain only a small part of wage stagnation. Edmond et al caution that breaking up large companies could hurt productivi­ty, especially if the giants are more efficient. And Van Reenen argues that changes in informatio­n technology and globalisat­ion, rather than weakened antitrust law, are the culprit behind the rise of dominant companies, by creating winner-take-all markets.

Nor are all economists joining the fight. Interestin­gly, those who are sounding the alarm tend to be researcher­s who study labour, public finance, trade and macroecono­mics. Economists in industrial organisati­on, the field traditiona­l focused on assessing the effects of mergers and market power, have been relatively muted -- in fact, the number of empirical studies assessing the impacts of mergers after the fact has been curiously low for a number of years. A cynical interpreta­tion is that this may be due to industry capture; economists specialisi­ng in this area may not want to jeopardise their future ability to land lucrative pro-merger consulting gigs.

But overall, economists are growing more concerned about the threat posed by corporate power. The budding antitrust movement will offer them valuable ideas, data and intellectu­al heft in its quest to stem the rampant power of industrial giants

 ??  ?? NOAH SMITH
NOAH SMITH

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India