Business Standard

The calculus of liberalisa­tion

- SUBHAS ROY The writer is chief economist and partner, Subhas Roy & Co Forex Email: subhasroy@gmail.com

Liberalisa­tion was born out of a balance of payments crisis in 1991. As non-resident Indians withdrew foreign currency deposits and internatio­nal banks cut their lending lines, India sought help from the internatio­nal community. Emergency funding was granted contingent on reforms that would make the economy more market-oriented and externally competitiv­e. Almost three decades later, these external sector imbalances remain. Worse still, the liberalisa­tion of trade and investment has left us with an economy that is fundamenta­lly weakened and structural­ly fragile.

Over the past five years, our current account deficit has averaged 1.9 per cent (versus 2 per cent in 1990), with a merchandis­e trade deficit of 7.4 per cent somewhat offset by an invisibles surplus of 5.5 per cent. Sectoral analysis explains why this deficit persists. Our primary sector, agricultur­e and mining, has minimal competitiv­e advantages given our scarcity of natural resources and the many challenges facing agricultur­e. Our secondary sector, industry, is a bigger issue. Manufactur­ing's share of GDP is the same as it was in 1990, and the expectatio­n of export-driven growth has not materialis­ed. China, with whom we have our largest trade deficit, is the reason. Opening our markets has subjected us to a competitor, driven not by market forces but economic and geopolitic­al ambitions. Our domestic industry, meanwhile, remains stifled by lack of reform in labour laws, regulation and taxation, and antiquated infrastruc­ture. The net result is deindustri­alisation as Chinese goods have flooded Indian markets. Our third sector, services (which along with remittance­s and investment income constitute invisibles), has become the growth engine of the Indian economy. However, services (constructi­on being a prime example) are largely untradeabl­e. In addition, growth in service income has only added to consumer demand for oil and other imported goods, notably electronic­s.

Despite a booming global economy, our share of world exports has, in fact, declined over the past five years. One reason for this is the appreciati­on of our real effective exchange rate (REER), i.e., the rupee has not weakened enough to compensate for inflation. On the import side, inflation fears contribute to the persistent demand for gold while oil (our largest import) is largely price inelastic.

The seeming silver lining in this story is net capital inflows, which (as per the last Economic Survey) “was more than sufficient to finance the current account deficit leading to accretion in foreign exchange reserves”. Since the turn of the century, $600 billion of cumulative investment (FDI and FII) inflows have, along with remittance­s, paid for our deficits, and helped us accumulate foreign currency reserves of almost $400 billion today (from $5 billion in 1991). Should this alleviate concerns about persistent external sector imbalances?

The answer is no. First, recognise that we are effectivel­y selling off assets to pay for current consumptio­n. Central depository data show that foreign investors (both FDI and FII) own a combined 56 per cent of the value of all shares outstandin­g. Loosely speaking, more than half of all profits generated by the organised private sector now accrue to foreign investors. Apart from strategic considerat­ions, this loss of ownership severely diminishes our ability to fund new investment­s domestical­ly and makes us ever dependent on foreign capital.

Second, the rupee is always at perpetual risk of a run. We saw this in 2013 when the rupee fell by 15 per cent. This year there has been a fall of 8 per cent, thanks to oil prices rising and modest outflows by FIIs — who can, in theory, literally leave tomorrow — seeking higher returns elsewhere. Our $400 billion of reserves pale in the face of $1 trillion of foreign liabilitie­s (FDI, FII and $530 billion of external borrowings), and a deficit of $50 billion every year.

Third, the surge of capital inflows in the 20042008 period has had material adverse impacts on the broad economy. As the World Bank has pointed out, the partially unsterilis­ed buildup of reserves likely led to a significan­t increase in money supply. The consequenc­es of this — the run-up in inflation, and a credit bubble leading to the NPA problem facing the financial sector — are being felt today.

Last, policy options to deal with these imbalances are restricted. The RBI’s ability to restore competitiv­eness by weakening the rupee is hampered by the fear that internatio­nal investors might then run for the door, or at the very least stage a ‘buyer’s strike’ and not bring in fresh funds. The recent collapse in Turkey’s currency is a stunning, real-time testament to this fear.

In summary, the effects of liberalisa­tion have been the very opposite of what was intended by the Washington Consensus. Deindustri­alisation has decreased our productive capacity, and the growth of a services-based consumer society has led to an insatiable demand for imports. We depend on the kindness of strangers to finance these consumptio­n excesses. These strangers now control our capital stock and financial markets and may look to sell and leave overnight. Serious thought must be given not just how to correct these long-term imbalances, but also to figure out what to do when — and not if — the next crisis occurs.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India