Business Standard

Pricing social returns in economic growth

The government needs to play an active role in encouragin­g basic research as well as protecting the environmen­t

- MAITREESH GHATAK The writer is professor of economics, London School of Economics

At first, the news that Paul Romer and William Nordhaus have jointly received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics for integratin­g technologi­cal innovation­s and climate change in the analysis of economic growth seemed a bit surprising. There has been some buzz about a prize for endogenous technologi­cal change in the air for a while, as has been a prize for the emerging field of environmen­tal economics, and both Romer and Nordhaus are obvious frontrunne­rs in these respective areas. What seemed surprising at first was the pairing of the two. But upon reflection, it seems like a rather innovative decision on part of the Prize Committee, and particular­ly apt in the current era where innovation and technologi­cal change are literally in the palm of our hands and yet unchecked growth and climate change bode disaster for the planet.

Romer’s work examines what drives technologi­cal change that enables growth in productivi­ty and allows society to escape the limits to growth due to scarce resources. Nordhaus’ work explores how we can achieve sustainabl­e growth taking into account the effect of economic activity on climate change. Technologi­cal change expands our ability to enjoy higher standards of living while the environmen­t puts natural bounds on how much we can grow. Researches on these questions are, therefore, closely linked and yet, study forces that are somewhat in tension with one another, one pushing us forward and the other holding us back, like yin and yang in Chinese philosophy.

The field of economic growth studies the factors causing variation in levels and growth rates of per capita income over time and across countries. Research in this area is driven by the following questions: What forces drive long-run growth, and what are the constraint­s that put limits to growth? Robert Solow, a pioneer in the field, won the Nobel Prize for his contributi­ons to the theory of economic growth in 1987. Solow’s growth framework represents the classical view of developmen­t. In a world where markets and government­s work well, and individual­s make savings and work decisions optimally trading off current and future consumptio­n, the problem of growth is essentiall­y one of accumulati­ng capital stock through savings and investment.

The growth framework developed by Solow had two major limitation­s. Romer and Nordhaus’ work extended it in two different directions to address these.

First, Solow’s theory does not actually explain long-run growth. As a country accumulate­s more capital, the returns to investment diminish as there are fixed factors, such as land and natural resources, as well as knowledge and technology. The gains from having more and more machines or workers at some point get exhausted. Therefore, eventually, a country’s growth rate slows down and without changes in productivi­ty, would become zero. Moreover, the standard growth model predicts that poor countries will grow faster, as they have little capital and so high rates of returns -- just like children grow faster, adults slow down. This is a prediction that finds little support in data.

Second, despite its popularity, per capita income has many limitation­s as an index of developmen­t as it only captures the value of goods and services that money can buy. It does not consider important determinan­ts of our quality of life such as the environmen­t, as that is not bought and sold in the market. Also, when we calculate national income, we allow for the depreciati­on of the capital stock needed to generate it but do not factor in the devaluatio­n or depletion of natural resources. Yet, unlike buildings, infrastruc­ture and machinery, natural resources cannot be rebuilt or replenishe­d when needed.

Given that economics is all about pricing and allocating scarce factors, why were both technologi­cal change and the environmen­t taken to be outside the domain of its analysis until recently? Because both are examples of public goods where the standard economic logic fails. An idea or a blueprint, once produced can be replicated infinitely at zero cost. Similarly, how does one price clean air or water? Unlike a standard good such as an apple, in these cases, your consumptio­n does not reduce mine, and also, it is difficult to apply a “no pay no use” policy, both of which are essential for a good or a service to have a market. Because of this, left to market forces, there will be too little innovation (as inventors often don’t get to capture their share of the benefits without adequate patent protection) and too much pollution (as there is no cost of doing it, unlike the cost of utilities such as electricit­y or water or heating).

Romer’s contributi­on lies in bringing innovation within the purview of analysis, and providing a better understand­ing of what kind of market conditions and government policies regarding patents and investment in R&D can raise the long-run rate of growth. Nordhaus’ contributi­on lies in studying the two-way interactio­n between economic activity and the climate, and how they would co-evolve over time, and the role of policies, such as carbon taxes, to better align the goals of material prosperity and environmen­tal sustainabi­lity. Both also highlight the limitation­s of the market-fundamenta­list view. In both cases market prices capture the private but not the social returns, requiring the government to play an active role in encouragin­g basic research as well as protecting the environmen­t. Without these, we would kill the goose that lays the golden eggs.

 ?? ILLUSTRATI­ON BY BINAY SINHA ??
ILLUSTRATI­ON BY BINAY SINHA
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India