Business Standard

Kalecki insights on fiscal, monetary plans

- RATHIN ROY The writer is Director, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy. Views are personal

The coordinati­on of fiscal and monetary policy is a difficult challenge for all economies. Coordinati­ng fiscal and monetary policy involves specifying an analytical framework that is shared by the institutio­ns responsibl­e for these policies, namely, the government and the central bank. Without such a framework there is dissonance about individual policy actions, to the detriment of the national economic discourse.

Michal Kalecki provided a useful and relevant analysis of the issues involved 50 years ago, carefully characteri­sing the problem separately for advanced and developed economies, and also considerin­g the problem in the

Indian context. Kalecki’s contempora­ry relevance was brought to my attention by Niranjan Rajadhyaks­ha of the IDFC institute. The recently concluded Jackson Hole meeting of central bankers and economists focussed on two concerns central to Kalecki: The role of market power (impacting aggregate supply) and inequality(impacting aggregate demand) in fiscal and monetary decision making.

In the Indian context, the important Kaleckian question, different from Keynes, is not how growth is to be financed but at whose expense? Agreement on an inflation target is very important for a country focused on inclusive growth. Inflation can act as a tax on the poor, especially if it is driven by rising prices of necessitie­s. Demand management therefore involves agreement that inflation must be controlled by targeting aggregate inflationa­ry expectatio­ns using interest rates, but equally, using instrument­s of taxation and transfers to ensure that relative prices of non-essentials are at levels that do not result in an increase in luxury consumptio­n, which would both reduce savings and increase imports. Policies to secure these objectives must be co-ordinated.

On the supply side, maximising growth requires the Indian economy to deliver public and private goods that cater to home market demand at affordable prices, and that grow exports. This is financed through taxation and the deployment of domestic and foreign savings. Ideally, a revenue surplus combined with borrowing from domestic saving would finance public investment, with private investment financed by domestic saving, and by foreign direct and portfolio investment­s. Monetary authoritie­s have to make explicit their considerat­ion of these questions in credit and inflation policy design. Equally, when the central government runs a revenue deficit, and the bulk of borrowing is used for consumptio­n, fiscal prudence becomes important and the impact on inflation-and on imports — of such deficit financing becomes a legitimate question for considerat­ion by monetary authoritie­s.

There is disharmony between fiscal and monetary policy when the shared economic framework does not deliver agreement on the trade-offs. For example, if growth is seen to be generated by increases in demand for consumptio­n, then it is necessary to agree when such growth will falter due to lack of supply response. Equally, if domestic public debt is being used to finance consumptio­n, and not investment, then it is important to recognise that this would worsen the income distributi­on without correspond­ing benefit. This is because the interest paid on domestic debt accrues to savers and in a developing economy savers tend to be richer. If debt is used for investment, then we can live with the adverse distributi­onal consequenc­es. But if debt, and not taxes, pays for consumptio­n, then there is no gain to balance the adverse distributi­onal impact. This reason for fiscal prudence is extremely important for the practice of macroecono­mic trade craft in India, but has been sidelined by those who practice the now discredite­d “crowding out” macroecono­mics of the Thatcherit­e age, which has been abandoned even by the IMF and the central bankers at Jackson Hole.

Kalecki also paid careful attention to the role of finance in perpetuati­ng the concentrat­ion of economic power. He had two important insights. First, investment may be limited not because of credit constraint­s (as in developed economies) but because of the unwillingn­ess of entreprene­urs to finance investment. Second, finance maybe directed to activities (such as speculatio­n) which would maximise individual gain, but not growth. A purely macro-prudential approach to credit policy is not adequate in these circumstan­ces. Here, the coordinati­on of fiscal and credit policy is of the first importance. Even if banks are publicly owned, (as in India) it may well be the case that credit flows are not availed by growth generating investment­s; if, in addition, the allocation of credit is dominated by a handful of large corporates, then an element of monopoly can enter the picture, and there could be a trade-off between fiduciary prudence and equity in credit dispositio­n to important sources of growth like agricultur­e and SMEs.

I use the Kaleckian lens to make two points: first, as recognised at Jackson Hole, orthodox thinking about fiscal-monetary co-ordination is no longer adequate given country-specific circumstan­ce. Second, the basis for discussion about difference­s in opinion regarding specific fiscal, monetary or credit policy decisions must be discussed within a shared (not necessaril­y Kaleckian) analytical framework. Invoking fear of market wrath or citing temporary benchmarks of economic health only serves as fodder to the commentari­atfor damaging speculatio­n about institutio­nal acrimony. In conversati­ons among policy makers with collective responsibi­lity for coordinate­d action, difference­s in point of view will occur. Their collective resolution must be based on economic and political rationale, and not on considerat­ions of turf or perceived difference­s in responsibi­lity. Avoiding fiscal or monetary dominance is a shared institutio­nal responsibi­lity, and history will assign collective blame or credit for success or failure on this score.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India