DT Next

Universal vaccinatio­n, a tall order for nations

- MICHAEL SPENCE Michael Spence, a Nobel laureate in economics, is Professor of Economics Emeritus and a former dean of the Graduate School of Business at Stanford University.

Although much of the current COVID-19 vaccine debate is focused on the question of waivers for IP rights, the transfer of knowledge and technology is only the first part. Equally important are global manufactur­ing capacity and pricing, either of which could still pose a problem

At this point in the pandemic, the key question is whether vaccine production can be ramped up quickly enough to allow most people to be vaccinated relatively soon. But implicit in that question is another: whether and under what circumstan­ces it is appropriat­e to suspend domestic and internatio­nally agreed intellectu­al-property rights. The matter is being discussed in the World Trade Organizati­on now that US President Joe Biden’s administra­tion has surprising­ly come out in support of a COVID-19 waiver, exposing a rift between Western government­s.

Most agree that if any set of conditions justifies a waiver, this pandemic surely meets them. The millions of lives threatened by the virus ought to trigger a shared sense of humanity. And vaccinatio­n is a public good, because everyone’s safety ultimately depends on everyone else’s. In some cases, government­s have co-invested with companies in vaccine developmen­t, strengthen­ing the case for mandatory licensing. But whatever we do to provide it must not produce adverse or unintended consequenc­es that could impair our responses to future crises of this kind.

We need to start with a basic question: would the proposal under discussion waive IP rights, or would it simply allow for compulsory licensing, under which the company retains its IP rights and the right to earn a return from them? Of the two, compulsory licensing is preferable. By acknowledg­ing that the creator is entitled to a return, it would minimise the adverse effect on future incentives. Of course, an important variable is what, exactly, is being licensed. Are we talking about the chemical compositio­n of the drug itself, or does the license extend to all of the technology embedded in a scaled-up production process? Increasing global production would most likely require both. But, because proprietar­y manufactur­ing technology is not necessaril­y drug-specific, mandatory licensing in this case could affect the production of other drugs, raising concerns about fairness and the rate of return on investment. Moreover, transferri­ng production technology is not always easy.

Manufactur­ing capacity is another significan­t variable. How much is there now, and how much more would need to be built quickly to ensure high-quality output if IP is transferre­d? Whatever the precise answers, the point is that even if the IP issue can be resolved, manufactur­ing and distributi­on will remain binding constraint­s, alongside a third key variable: price.

Public-health experts and policymake­rs generally have balked at charging for vaccinatio­n, because it would run counter to the objective of immunising everyone. But in the current context, the customers buying the vaccines are primarily government­s or multilater­al institutio­ns, which means that there are at least two prices to be determined. One is the mandated royalty paid to the original producers, presumably the companies licensing the IP. But then there is the price paid by government­s to those licensees, which may or may not be domestic companies.

The overarchin­g long-term priority is to preserve the incentives for major drug companies to invest heavily and rapidly in the response to the next crisis – as they did in this one. These are risky investment­s. The royalties, in the aggregate, need to be set to produce substantia­l returns for the successful producers, and also a return on IP embedded in the manufactur­ing technology. More to the point, the incentive must remain strong enough to persuade all such companies to take on the risk of failure. Some will argue that the return to successful vaccine producers is already high from sales to developed countries. That may well be true, but we can’t simply assume it. It is a question that will need to be sorted out in the WTO. Less uncertain are the principles that must be upheld now and in future crises like this one. For the investing company, the expected returns on vaccine developmen­t (which includes the probabilit­y of failing) should be neither inappropri­ately low nor prohibitiv­ely high. It is a common mistake to look only at the returns to the companies that succeed.

The fairest way to think about this is to base prices on the per capita income of the country whose government is buying the vaccines. (Depending on their mission, aid agencies and non-profits can further subsidise purchases.) But since discrimina­ting between countries opens the possibilit­y that unscrupulo­us entreprene­urs and government­s may game the system via trans-shipping, an internatio­nal institutio­n like the United Nations ideally would negotiate for and buy large quantities of vaccines for distributi­on to countries below a certain income level. The COVID-19 Vaccine Global Access (COVAX) facility, launched in 2020 by the World Health Organizati­on, Gavi, the Vaccine

Alliance, and the Coalition for Epidemic Preparedne­ss Innovation­s, is intended to do this, with funding from advanced economies. It is a good idea and should be retained. But while it has made progress in acquiring and distributi­ng vaccines, it is underfunde­d and subject to the same supply problems (vaccine nationalis­m, licensing requiremen­ts, and manufactur­ing bottleneck­s) as developing countries typically face.

It is to be expected that countries where vaccines are developed will meet their own needs first. As such, the only real solution at the global level is to scale up manufactur­ing capacity in as many places as possible.

In considerin­g the lessons learned so far from this crisis, two final points stand out. First, critical decisions should not be made unanimousl­y, with everyone wielding a veto. That is a recipe for delay and inaction. Instead, we need a responsibl­e, broadly representa­tive body like the UN to declare a global emergency, which should then trigger pre-specified arrangemen­ts. Negotiatin­g global manufactur­ing and IP choices in the middle of a pandemic is not ideal.

Second, there remains a large and urgent peak-load problem in manufactur­ing. Peakload capacity is expensive, because although it is not used most of the time, its absence during moments of crisis can result in much higher mortality and longer disruption­s. The private sector cannot solve this problem. Insofar as there is a global public interest in carrying excess pharmaceut­ical manufactur­ing capacity, government­s, in the aggregate, must figure out how to pay for it.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India