Hindustan Times (Amritsar)

TN SRINIVASAN, ECONOMIST FOR ALL SEASONS, DIES AT 85

- Niranjan Rajadhyaks­ha feedback@livemint.com ■ The writer is research director and senior fellow at IDFC Institute.

MUMBAI: Srinivasan, or TN, as he was widely known, initially trained to be a statistici­an. He studied at the Indian Statistica­l Institute in Kolkata. An uninspirin­g stint in Mumbai, doing statistica­l quality control at the textile mills, led him to write to Tjalling Koopmans at Yale University.

Koopmans, who would later win the 1975 Nobel Prize in economics, took the young Indian under his wing. Under the master, Srinivasan studied operations research and linear programmin­g, skills that were especially important in the age of national planning, when resources were sought to be optimally allocated with minimal recourse to the price system. Srinivasan wrote his doctoral thesis on the choice of techniques. Amartya Sen was grappling with the same issue at the same time at Cambridge University, under the guidance of Joan Robinson.

TN returned to India to join the Indian Statistica­l Institute in New Delhi in 1962. He also worked with the Planning Commission at a time when the government was brimming with young economics talent, including Srinivasan, Sen, Jagdish Bhagwati, VK Ramaswami, Pranab Bardhan and BS Minhas in New Delhi; and Deena Khatkhate, Anand Chandavark­ar, VV Bhatt and M Narasimham in Mumbai.

Srinivasan found himself doing work for the perspectiv­e planning division headed by the formidable Pitambar Pant. Its task was to assess the economic needs of the country over the 15 years from 1961 to 1976. One of the products of the division, with Srinivasan playing an active role, was on an issue that has become resonant in our times—basic minimum income for all Indians. Srinivasan and Bardhan would later write in 1974: “The stage has come when we should sharply focus our efforts on providing an assured minimum income to every citizen of the country within a reasonable period of time. Progressiv­ely this minimum itself should be raised as developmen­t goes apace.”

The next few decades would see Srinivasan write a series of technical papers on statistics, trade theory, economic developmen­t, agricultur­e and microecono­mics. As the economist VN Balasubram­anyam wrote in an introducti­on to an interview with Srinivasan, few scholars can list among their publicatio­ns both A Note On Approximat­ion To Finite Sample Moments Of Estimation Whose Exact Sampling Distributi­on is Unknown and Destitutio­n: A Discourse. No wonder he was a fellow of both the Econometri­c Society and the American Philosophi­cal Society.

A four-volume handbook of developmen­t economics that Srinivasan edited in collaborat­ion with Hollis Chenery is a landmark. He was also an influentia­l teacher at Yale, what Suman Bery has called his intellectu­al home, where Reserve Bank of India governor Urjit Patel was one of his doctoral students.

However, his most influentia­l work was in creating the intellectu­al groundwork for economic reforms. The triumvirat­e of Bhagwati, Padma Desai and Srinivasan constitute­d the intellectu­al vanguard of the movement that eventually saw India move away from import substituti­on towards a re-engagement with the world economy. Theirs were lonely voices in the wilderness when they first began to question Indian economic policies. One of the first salvos was fired by Bhagwati and Desai in their 1970 book, India: Planning For Industrial­isation. Srinivasan collaborat­ed with them as well.

Some of their earlier econometri­c work showed that the sharp devaluatio­n of the rupee in 1966 had indeed helped close the trade gap. Later, Bhagwati and Srinivasan wrote a profound critique of the Indian economic policy. Their book on Indian foreign trade regimes and economic developmen­t, for the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) in 1975, is a classic. This book is a masterclas­s in policy economics.

It is thus no surprise that Srinivasan was a strong supporter of the 1991 economic reforms. His debates with the Marxist economist Ashok Rudra in the pages of the Economic and Political Weekly at the time are a lesson in how intellectu­al debates are to be conducted. It is also no surprise that Manmohan Singh turned to the Bhagwati-Srinivasan duo to do an assessment of the economic reforms for the Union ministry of finance in 1993. Srinivasan was an iconoclast when required. His targets included protection­ism, foreign aid, basic needs and the human developmen­t index. I have seen him in action in a few academic seminars in India, where his sharp questions made even senior economists break into a sweat. His bluntness was legendary, as was the loyalty he attracted from his best students.

Srinivasan was among that rare breed of economists who are equally at ease with technical skills, policy debates and broader philosophi­cal implicatio­ns. John Maynard Keynes once described the ideal economist: “He must be mathematic­ian, historian, statesman, philosophe­r—in some degree… He must be purposeful and disinteres­ted in a simultaneo­us mood; as aloof and incorrupti­ble as an artist, yet sometimes as near to earth as a politician.”Srinivasan epitomized these qualities.

 ??  ??
 ?? TWITTER@VDEHEJIA ?? ■ TN Srinivasan
TWITTER@VDEHEJIA ■ TN Srinivasan

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India