Hindustan Times (Bathinda)

‘We balanced needs, efficiency, equity’

-

The Constituti­on, through Article 280 to 281, provides for finance commission­s every five years as a mechanism for sharing of taxes and revenues vertically between the Centre and states; and horizontal­ly among all states, based on levels of developmen­t, demographi­c outcomes, prosperity and regional needs.

The final report of the 15th Finance Commission for 2021-26 has now been made public. The Union government, in its action taken report on the commission’s report tabled in Parliament, has accepted most of the recommenda­tions, and overtly rejected none. The 15th FC had the onerous task of devolving resources at a time when the pandemic has devastated the economy, shrinking the resource pie. The chairman of the 15th FC, NK Singh, spoke to Zia Haq about the report. Edited excerpts:

What were the philosophi­cal underpinni­ngs and approach of the 15th FC? Your report states that “stability and predictabi­lity of resources is an essential component of good longterm budgeting for both Union and States”.

The history of the Finance Commission is embedded in the legacy of unalloyed confidence and trust. When the Constituen­t Assembly in its debates was unable to come to a conclusion of how the resources were to be divided between the Union and states, various mechanisms were considered at that time. Earlier it was said that nothing was shareable, except income tax, and you know the finance commission in a sense is older than our Constituti­on, because the Independen­ce was in 1947, whereas the Constituti­on came into play only in 1950. So, there was a period they had appointed an interim chairman of the finance commission under CD Deshmukh because the Constituen­t Assembly had asked him to do it. He had given a certain framework on the division of resources. Then the Constituti­on got adopted and the 1st FC under KC Neogi was constitute­d. Since then it has had an unbroken legacy, an unbroken record embedded in bipartisan­ship, fair play and has been totally ideologica­lly neutral.

In terms of receiving the requests, each of the states and the Union government… and then looking at what would be their expenditur­e, looking at their likely revenue, what would be a fair distributi­on of these resources between the entities of the Union and the states, and thereafter what would be a reasonable basis for allocation. And if there were obvious gaps after the revenue expenditur­e of the state had been calibrated in an optimum way and the revenues had been projected in a somewhat optimistic way.

Now, if there were inescapabl­e gaps, what amount of it was reasonable to fill up by taking recourse to Article 275 of the Constituti­on, by way of revenue-deficit grants.

Thereafter, two big changes took place. One was that the third tier (urban local bodies and panchayats) was brought into play by the two constituti­onal amendments (73rd and 74th), which assigned responsibi­lities to the FCS and second, the Disaster Management Act 2005 was enacted and it became customary for assignment of resources for disaster management. Also, it gave greater latitude to the President in asking the FC’S views on any other matter which the president may choose in the interest of sound finance.

Over these 72 years or so, the dynamics of the Indian economy have changed enormously. From an economy originally depended on imported foodgrains and scrambling for shortage of foreign exchange to an economy, given the liberalisa­tion and successive crisis, that has matured and evolved, we see that the needs and obligation­s from the states have increased.

There are two important points. One is the recognitio­n that the Union government had obligation­s that went beyond the strict interpreta­tion of the 7th Schedule of the Constituti­on (which specifies allocation of subjects between Union and states, containing three lists: Union list, state list and concurrent list), namely what went beyond what was assigned to the Union government in terms of taking care of national priorities of the states.

The birth of centrally sponsored schemes and the central outlays… these were important changes. Second was that the number of states increased rather significan­tly, many states required special treatment particular­ly, those who have a small population, hilly terrain etc. So these transforma­tive changes have led to the evolution of the role, responsibi­lity and obligation of the FCS.

What states look forward to most in every report is the devolution formula, which you have maintained. It’s 41%, with a 1% downward adjustment (from 42% earlier) because of two new Union territorie­s. You assigned a weight of 12.5% for demographi­c performanc­e, which is the inverse of the fertility rate. You have said the 2011 Census better represents the needs of states. Was the biggest challenge for you was to not penalise efficient states, demographi­cally speaking, at the cost of the inefficien­t?

When the 15th FC was constitute­d, there were great worries. In the terms of reference, the President asked the commission to use the data of the 2011 Census in respect of the population criteria if population was to be used as a criterion for purposes of the assignment of the horizontal distributi­on. Then, there were strong protests by some states, particular­ly the southern states, because they would be big losers because they had controlled population well. It was argued that it would result in rewarding the inefficien­t and penalising the efficient. It was a challenge to therefore deal with this conundrum. We had no option because use of the 2011 data was a given fact by the president. It is the president’s right to assign a particular way in which we look at the criteria. Now, what are the options we had?

One option, which was a hypothetic­al option, was... in total neglect of any past practice to ignore population completely as a criterion and to do it on the basis of some other criterion. The Constituti­on doesn’t bind me to use any particular criterion. But then we came to the conclusion that let us see what else could we have used.

Some suggestion­s were made that maybe we could do it on the basis of per capita income. The result would have been that again the states that have the lowest per capita income would have the highest population density. In effect it would have meant that those states where rates of growth had been poor would get rewarded unduly and states with higher growth rates would get penalised. So the income distance criteria would begin to also mirror this phenomenon.

So we went back to the drawing board and said, why not take the bull by the horn? Why not face the problem squarely and say, yes, there’s an X amount which used to be historical­ly given on the basis of weightage to population in the horizontal formula and now we have to use the 2011 (population data) and break that into two parts. One part you give it on the basis of population, whatever weight you assign, and two, you actively reward states that have managed their demography better; which reflects what? Namely, greater investment­s they have made in girl-child education, managed their health parameters better, and have got a better governance matrix. So, in many ways assigning a positive weight in demographi­c management embedded the investment­s those states had made in the social sector particular­ly health and education. We found that in this way we would be able to mitigate any adverse consequenc­es to some extent of what would be the outcome.

Broadly speaking, in this horizontal distributi­on, there are three important factors which we have pointed out in the report. We have sought to balance need, efficiency and equity. The population reflects the need; the weight given to geographic­al area represents the need; the income distance criterion, namely the per capita income, represents the equity part. In what way are we rewarding efficiency? By giving weightage to the demographi­c criteria and also giving some weightage to the fiscal achievemen­ts to the state. So in some ways therefore if you look at these, each of these criteria...the forest area also represents the need... are evenly divided in some ways.

Many of the southern states were extremely nervous about what would happen to them. They feared that they would be penalised for getting their population under control. Do you think you have adequately addressed those concerns now?

Adequacy is a subjective norm. The best way this would have been addressed is a situation where we hadn’t used population as a criteria at all. But then I explained you would have had other kind of choices. Instead of saying ‘adequately addressed’, let me say ‘reasonably mitigated’, or ‘responsibl­y mitigated’. The concern of the southern states was not only the award of the 15th FC, but they looked a bit ahead -- that if, for the purpose of the delimitati­on of the constituen­cies, this was going to be the pattern of using the most contempora­ry population census data, what would happen in terms of the nature their representa­tion in Parliament and the size of their Assemblies, and therefore the number of the seats they would elect to Rajya Sabha. That was fortunatel­y not a concern with us but I know that embedded in their minds was also this particular concern.

You could say that we have tried to in some ways redress this in a manner we considered appropriat­e. In spite of what we did as we had done, to mitigate this , it turned out to be that many of the states would have had a huge yawning resource deficit. That is why, ₹2.95 lakh crore given by way of revenue-deficit grants... if you look at the states who are beneficiar­ies of this, huge amount has gone to Andhra Pradesh, huge amount has gone to Kerala.

Kerala was one of the states where the demographi­c management was one of the best. Some has gone to Telangana. The way we have calibrated these revenue-deficit grants, we looked at this... as you can see there’s one full volume in the report devoted to the states. We subjected each of the states to very careful scrutiny, then we worked out what would be the minimum inescapabl­e revenue expenditur­e, we compressed that and calculated the maximum amount of resources that they were likely to generate on a normative basis and concluded that this is the inescapabl­e gap between the inescapabl­e minimum expenditur­e and what is likely to be the optimum revenue.

We have therefore assigned revenue-deficit grants. A fair amount of that has gone to states who would have been the unaddresse­d factor in spite of the mitigation on account of the use of the 2011 data. Have we succeeded totally? One classic example to be honest is that we have not been able to take care of, for instance, Karnataka because it has managed its finances in a reasonable way and their expenditur­es have been very low and their revenues have been reasonable. So I have no answer to this question. A state like Karnataka I was not able to give revenue-deficit grant. I couldn’t reinvent a formula to overcome this handicap. I did try to address the concerns of Karnataka by giving them some state-specific grants for the rejuvenati­on of lakes and water bodies and some important places, particular­ly rejuvenati­on of Bangalore and Mysore.

Do you think some states would still have reasonable grounds to complain?

Sure, I think that is quite legitimate. We must also recognise that for many FCS, the weightage given to per capita income was much more than what we have given. If we had stuck to those weightages, their injury would have been far more significan­t. The issue of equity would have got greatly compromise­d. The lowest per capita income is of Bihar. Bihar, UP and Rajasthan, these are known as the really backward states. You would recall that in the earlier government, they appointed a committee under Raghuram Rajan to come up with the multiple index on the backwardne­ss of states. In that multiple index Raghu had done at that time, Bihar and Odisha were at the rock bottom. In this case, Odisha has also done better subsequent to Raghu’s report; Odisha has managed its demography also well; so Odisha is not too happy. Maybe this will get mitigated when some of their special projects, such as the cyclone, get addressed.

You have recommende­d a fiscal glide path whose imprint is more or less clear in the Budget. You have also recommende­d a committee to review the Fiscal Responsibi­lity and Budget Management Act (FRBM).

What prompted this?

In the FRBM committee, which I chaired, what we were aiming at then and also during the terminal period of the 15th FC, was to look at the debt-to-gdp (ratio) to be 60% -- 40 for the central government, and 20 for the states. We had done a calibrated fiscaldefi­cit trajectory which would enable this level of debt to be reached. So that’s now embedded in history, and overtaken by events in a very dramatic way. We are no more in that world. The world has changed in some important respects: The pandemic permanentl­y changed the structure of the global economy. When I chaired the FRBM committee, the focus was the central government and as far as the states were concerned the committee said this would be left to a subsequent FC. I didn’t know then I was going to head that FC. But investors look at the general government debt. FDI looks to general government. So that FRBM which had reference to the central government, where states were not in the picture, has changed. That’s why I proposed that we need to have a fundamenta­l re-look at this overall framework, the changed global context and the changed national context in which we make the states and the central government equal partners. That is why I have not given a point (for fiscal deficit) both for the central government and the states, but a range (of fiscal deficit).

Why had I suggested a fixed point in the FRBM committee? The reason is in parliament­ary democracie­s, the tendency is to adhere to the upper end of the range given the populist pressures for public outlays.that logic doesn’t hold good anymore. Giving fixed number is to build in inflexibil­ity and I am increasing­ly coming around to the view that this framework needs not to be pro-cyclical, it needs to work in accordance with the tandem of the cycle; and therefore a cyclically adjusted fiscal deficit and debt norm would be more appropriat­e. I have given the states a leeway to go up to 4% and taper down to 3% (fiscal deficit) much later. I have given a 0.5% leeway for purposes of reform in the power sector. Why did I select [the] power [sector]? When I visited all the states, the giant and the gorilla in the room is power. Look at any state’s finances, it is the power sector and unbridged financial gaps in the power sector that is critical. The 0.5% headroom for borrowing by states was quite in line with what we had experience­d during our visit to states. If there is a shortfall in Goods and Services Tax compensati­on, and states have to borrow, that should not be debited against what we have proposed i.e. 4% and 0.5. The important thing I realised is that there no point in any debt framework which doesn’t involve the partnershi­p of the states.

Given the events of the last year, do you think our thinking of fiscal mathematic­s not just in India but the world has undergone a change?

I would say yes. Who else, if you think among the global economists, write and have written continuous­ly on this? I am not going to an extreme version like Larry Summers (former chief economist of the World Bank)... no Larry is not one who may be regarded as a fiscal fetishist, but there were others like Stanley Fischer (former vice chair of US Federal Reserve). Stan has been writing and saying that the entire literature in relation to the fiscal issue by eminent economists has undergone a rethink in terms of the importance of the role of public outlays, particular­ly on the need for them to play a proactive role on rejuvenati­ng of infrastruc­ture and more importantl­y employment, given in terms of what (labour-saving) technologi­es have done and also in terms of health and education. So I agree with you that the literature on fiscal policy has undergone a change.

To give you an anecdote, I was invited to give a lecture to the finance ministers of all Commonweal­th countries. The title of my lecture was fiscal forbearanc­e. People talk of monetary forbearanc­e. But I talked of fiscal forbearanc­e in times of this kind, which represents in some ways the changing ethos. Similarly, in the last OECD fiscal networking conference, the thinking on this fiscal issue has been an evolving one. OECD has been one of the flag carriers with regard to adherence to fiscal policies. The Germans have had a very strong influence if you recall. So all that... I agree entirely has undergone and is undergoing a change. In our federation, it’s much more important for the states to become increasing­ly involved in all of this. If I were to ask you a hypothetic­al question, that if there was no implicit guarantee upon the charge of the consolidat­ed fund of each individual state government, don’t you think that the market would have displayed their hesitation. For instance, if we looked anecdotall­y at the debt today of Punjab, it’s so high, and yet Punjab successful­ly borrows market developmen­t loans because there is an implicit state guarantee and unlike the US constituti­on, there is no such thing as federal bankruptcy. California can get bankrupt, I cannot imagine any state becoming bankrupt. The issue of the sovereign guarantee -- that’s why I think we need to consider the states and the Centre in a holistic way.

The hobbling implementa­tion of GST has been a structural problem and the 15th FC has made key recommenda­tions to reform it, including simplifyin­g the inverted duty structure. Your comments.

I have a feeling that there is deep realisatio­n on the part of the finance minister, reflected in the statement I have seen by the revenue secretary on this issue of GST, and he was asked this pointed question maybe by your paper, about the 15th FC recommenda­tion in our fairly robust chapter on resources (Chapter 5, Volume I), and what he intended to do. He said ‘these are all work in progress’ and because of the pandemic, the GST Council has not been able to deliberate on them. I think clearly on this whole story of invoice matching, you could see the budget talking on this, on invoice manipulati­on, and in terms of much better compliance... you see there are fundamenta­l issues of the inverted duty structure, there are issues of moving towards a more standardis­ed set of rates. I am not wanting to take the extreme view of one rate only but you can have one standard rate, one merit (goods) rate and one which may be called the penal rate but no more than three (rates) and we have said so. It is our expectatio­n and sanguine belief that our key suggestion­s would be considered by the GST Council. It is of vital concern. I’m happy to say the finance minister and finance secretary are acutely aware of all of this and will take it as soon as things return to normalcy.

You have said that the efficiency measure of the GST is around 50% and can be taken up to advanced economy benchmarks of 60%. What else will it take?

The literature on how and what has been called the revenue-neutral rate and there’s been a lot of debate on this. I recall that years ago, when the idea of GST had begun to take shape and I was still the revenue secretary, we had worked out a revenue-neutral rate, which was in the region of 14-15%. The average rate what we see now is 11%. What I mean really is that these are not necessaril­y raising rates but these are within the entire basket that you need to recalibrat­e in a manner which would approximat­e what would be regarded by economists a revenue-neutral rate. That would mean a deeper rationalis­ation in many ways. So I believe that the GST Council which I had the privilege to address once also believed that future FCS should have a greater partnershi­p with the GST Council because the two are very intimately connected.

You have looked at the whole idea of defence in somewhat innovative way and recommende­d creation of a nonlapsabl­e defence and security fund.

On defence, we got special terms of reference. It was not, so to say, spontaneou­s. I had the experience of working in the ministry of home also looking after paramilita­ry forces. In that sense I have a little bit of hangover. I realised having been expenditur­e secretary that there was a huge mismatch between the expenditur­e cycle and financial cycle of the defence ministry. The procuremen­ts are so complicate­d and the need to be clear of any controvers­y that by the time they are ready, the finances are not there. There is this inherent mismatch with regards to capital expenditur­e. Also, I realised the need for predictabi­lity and stability for the capital expenditur­e on the defence side. Keeping pace with technology often meant that they need a resource. So I played with many ideas. The other thing was how to make states partners in this process.

The issue of defence really transcends any list. I obtained many legal opinions on this. I obtained the opinion of (Kesava) Parasaran. When I had gone to the late Mr Jaitley, for whom I had great affection, I asked him that there is this complex issue which is troubling me; he said there is only one person who will know but will not give you the opinion. I said why, because he is 93 years old. Yet, I rang up Parasaran, who gave important opinions. One, he said I cannot play around what is in the divisible pool and there’s nothing I can to do to impose any condition on the resources from the divisible pool and that will have a constituti­onal infirmity. Second, he said there’s no question that the defence of India is of paramount responsibi­lity.

So then we were hard put to fund resources. I visited some of the defence establishm­ents. I visited Pangong, Leh, I saw some of the stuff. We said we must create a nonlapsabl­e defence fund and to bridge this asymmetric cycle. I had done so for the road cess. That how I came up with the non-lapsable fund and the funding of it. In defence funding what I have done, before the fund becomes a part of the divisible pool, you understand the gross revenue reciepts (GRR) and gross tax revenue (GTR), I calibrated the GRR by 1% and got the amount which I wanted, and added it to the monetisati­on of the surplus defence land, added it to the proceeds of the disinventm­ent of defence units, and added it to the liabilitie­s of different entities which owed to defence establishm­ents. So four sources of income outlined towards the creation of a non-lapsable fund.

Can you talk about any discomfort that states have right now with the new kind of fiscal federalist architectu­re that’s come in where it’s becoming increasing­ly difficult to sort of segregate matters of financial management of states?

I think that area also needs a rethink. Do you think if I had asked you the hypoptheti­cal question that the Seventh Schedule of the Constituti­on (the part which divides domains into central, states and joint Centre-states jurisdicti­on) has outlived its purpose, what would be the answer? In my view, yes. The Seventh Schedule decided to classify between the three categories... what would be in the exclusive category of the Union, exclusive domain of the states, and what would be in the concurrent list. There was a degree of clarity in that. Over a period of time, you have really transgress­ed from one end to the other.

Most of the centrally sponsored schemes are subjects which are classic subjects in the domain of the states, such as employment, food, education. You have now standalone parliament­ray legislatio­n, which are justiciabl­e, in areas such as employment like MNREGA, you have given a major boost to resources for right to education. Take for example a function number one for states, which is law and order. They have taken up a whole new centrally sponsored scheme under health. So the Seventh Schedule requires a revisit. So does the entry under Article 282 of the Constituti­on which has been used and misused for having all the centrally sponsored schemes.

 ?? SONU MEHTA/HT ARCHIVE ??
SONU MEHTA/HT ARCHIVE

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India