Hindustan Times (Chandigarh)

How to win elections, or pick winners

More than ‘representa­tiveness’, parties select candidates for their ‘winning ability’

- Neelanjan Sircar

In a well-functionin­g democracy, we should expect political parties to select candidates that best represent the interests of voters. Yet, as this column has previously demonstrat­ed, Members of Parliament (MPS) leave a lot to be desired when it comes to serving these interests. For instance, wealthier candidates are associated with poorer parliament­ary attendance and spending on constituen­cy developmen­t — all the more worrying as the scale of wealth has grown significan­tly in Indian electoral politics. If parties are not selecting candidates for the purposes of representa­tiveness, what criteria are used to select candidates?

Whether at the state or national level, party tickets for candidates are typically decided by a few party elites — a phenomenon political scientists describe as “low intraparty democracy.” The centralize­d nature of making laws in the Lok Sabha, combined with the fact that MPS are barred from “defecting” against their own party when voting in parliament, almost nullifies any institutio­nal role they can play in policymaki­ng. But if MPS are largely excluded from the policymaki­ng process, then parties have little incentive to select candidates that represent the interests of voters. Furthermor­e, there is little sense in expecting voters to vote for candidates based on how well they represent the interests of voters — it’s the party as a whole that must be held accountabl­e.

On the other hand, any serious political party aims to be in power, so the “winnabilit­y” of a candidate (namely the capacity to self-finance a campaign) is an important determinan­t in choosing candidates. We find ourselves in a scenario in which most candidates are selected neither for their ideologica­l commitment to a party, nor for the extent to which they seek to represent the interests of voters — they are chosen because they can win elections. Because candidates may trade their own capacity to win elections for party tickets, and have little role in policymaki­ng, they have little reason to be deeply committed to any political party.

The issue of candidate selection is fundamenta­l to understand­ing Indian politics. Unfortunat­ely, there exists no systematic data on how parties choose to hand out tickets to the candidates — as parties are understand­ably unwilling to let outsiders observe their selection processes.

To get some sense of candidate selection, this analysis looks at candidates who contested the 2009 election and received at least 20% vote share (irrespecti­ve of whether they won or lost) – a universe of 1020 candidates — and classifies whether they received a party ticket again in the 2014 election.

Only 354 of the 1020 candidates in the sample, approximat­ely 35%, were re-nominated in 2014. The data demonstrat­es that the winnabilit­y of a candidate is indeed a strong factor in renominati­on.

A candidate that was elected in 2009 had a 53% chance of being renominate­d, while a candidate that did not win the election in 2009 had only a 19% chance of being renominate­d. But renominati­on and incumbency are two very different phenomena, as winning is far from a sure thing upon renominati­on — even if a candidate won in 2009 and was re-nominated, he or she only had a 50% chance of winning again in 2014. The data also demonstrat­es that candidates are quite fickle in their partisan loyalties. About 12% of those renominate­d switched parties between 2009 and 2014 (with 23% of unelected candidates in 2009 switching parties upon renominati­on).

To understand how the background characteri­stics of MPS affected renominati­on rates, the analysis focused on three important characteri­stics: the moveable wealth of the candidate, which is important for financing campaigns; the existence of serious criminal cases pending because criminalit­y is correlated with organizati­onal capacity of the candidate; and whether the candidate has a post-graduate degree, which potentiall­y describes a candidates capacity to do the job.

A statistica­l model that measured the chances of renominati­on of a candidate as a function of these three characteri­stics (wealth, criminal cases, education) provided some interestin­g results.

The model suggests that a candidate that has a postgradua­te degree is about 28% more likely to be renominate­d as compared to a candidate without one, and a candidate with serious pending cases is 27% more likely to be renominate­d as compared to a candidate without them (see chart 2). A similar relationsh­ip is seen with wealth. A candidate with between Rs 10 and 50 lakh in moveable wealth has about a 34% probabilit­y of being renominate­d, while a crorepati (in terms of moveable wealth) is about 14% more likely to be renominate­d

(see chart1). Further statistica­l analysis suggests that the positive relationsh­ip between renominati­on and wealth and criminalit­y is due to the fact that those characteri­stics are associated with greater electabili­ty.

Clearly, the institutio­nal structure generates incentives for parties to select candidates who do not represent the interests of voters — rather focusing on those candidates more able to win elections. With the growing costs of elections, and little ideologica­l integrity to parties, we can only expect a greater disconnect between voters and their representa­tives in the future.

 ?? HT PHOTO ?? To understand how the background characteri­stics of MPS affected renominati­on, the analysis focused on 3 characteri­stics: the moveable wealth; existence of serious criminal cases pending; and whether the candidate has a postgradua­te degree.
HT PHOTO To understand how the background characteri­stics of MPS affected renominati­on, the analysis focused on 3 characteri­stics: the moveable wealth; existence of serious criminal cases pending; and whether the candidate has a postgradua­te degree.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India