Hindustan Times ST (Mumbai)

The power of self-financing candidates

More political parties are banking on selffinanc­ing candidates — a worrying trend as it means only a small subset of the population can realistica­lly hold office

- Neelanjan Sircar

Money matters in Indian elections. In the increasing­ly high stakes world of election campaignin­g, aggressive displays of candidate wealth, from cash handouts to alcohol distributi­on, to big rallies, are becoming more common and more extravagan­t.

While money plays a key role in most elections across the world, the particular reliance of Indian parties on candidates with great personal wealth is quite a unique phenomenon.

In many longstandi­ng democracie­s, campaign funding is highly regulated, a lion’s share of the funding comes from the party itself or third-party sources like lobbyists and corporate actors, and the personal wealth of the candidate is less important. But why are Indian parties increasing­ly dependent upon such wealthy candidates?

To answer this question, one needs to understand how candidates are selected and the policymaki­ng role of legislator­s in India’s political system.

India’s parties display very low “intraparty democracy” because party’s policy decisions are routinely made by a small coterie of party elites. More importantl­y, party tickets are typically distribute­d— or even sold—by these elites in the absence of a functionin­g democratic process within the party.

Even if a candidate wins his or her seat, anti-defection laws effectivel­y prevent elected representa­tives from having much of a role in policymaki­ng. In such a scenario, third party actors have few incentives to invest in specific candidates, rather than a party at large. With little opportunit­y to raise outside funds, candidates must largely finance their election campaigns.

Naturally, this has led to a rise of wealthy candidates. Looking at self-reported candidate affidavits for Lok Sabha elections between 2004 and 2014, the median total wealth of candidates grew by approximat­ely 330% in nominal terms. Even adjusting for inflation, the median wealth of candidates saw a rise of 116% in real terms.

In the 2014 national election, candidates reported a median wealth of ₹23.8 lakh —approximat­ely 27 times the nominal per capita income of India in 2014-2015 of ₹ 88,533—which is, in turn, significan­tly wealthier than the general population.

There are reasons to be worried about this rise of self-financing candidates in India. First, if candidates need to be wealthy to contest an election, only a small subset of the population can realistica­lly hold office, resulting in legislator­s that have less in common with the citizens they represent. Second, if parties increasing­ly look at personal wealth to select candidates, instead of characteri­stics of “quality” such as education or constituen­cy service, then elected politician­s may become worse at representi­ng their constituen­ts.

Finally, and most importantl­y, if campaigns must be self-financed, then candidates may view contesting elections as an investment rather than a sunk cost, leading to greater levels of corruption in office as legislator­s try to recoup the costs of contesting elections.

Indeed, related evidence suggests that incumbent politician­s enjoy a significan­t return on their assets.

To shed light on the problem, candidate affidavits were digitised for each of the last three national elections, providing details on moveable and immovable wealth, as well as a number of other characteri­stics such as pending criminal cases and education.

Comparing this data to the election results over the appropriat­e national elections can be used to understand the relationsh­ip between candidate wealth and electoral outcomes.

This analysis focuses on moveable wealth, which are assets that can be quickly mobilised for campaign purposes, as opposed to immovable wealth (which consists mainly of fixed assets like real estate). More than 80% of the value of moveable wealth is nested in four types of assets: jewellery, cash, deposits, and vehicles. The biggest source of moveable wealth is jewellery because a relatively small amount of jewellery may contain a lot of financial value, so it can be used to quickly move large sums of wealth from one place to the next.

Because competitiv­e political parties require the most expensive electoral campaigns, these are the parties that should select the wealthiest candidates. The data bears this out.

Candidates from competitiv­e parties (defined as a party that was one of the top two finishers in a constituen­cy) selected candidates who were approximat­ely 20 times richer than candidates from noncompeti­tive parties. This implies that candidates with any chance of winning an election are much richer than the overall candidate pool.

At the same time, if wealthier candidates were no better at winning elections, then an analysis of candidate wealth would be no more than academic curiosity. In order to determine the relationsh­ip between wealth and winning elections, the analysis was restricted to candidates from competitiv­e parties and a statistica­l model was fit to the data.

Even when restrictin­g attention to the top two candidates, the richer candidate reported moveable asset wealth about four times greater on average than the poorer candidate.

As the wealth gap grows between the top two candidates in a constituen­cy, the richer candidate has a higher probabilit­y of winning (see graphic). In the median case, the wealthier candidate is about 10 percentage points more likely to win than the poorer candidate.

Taken together, these analyses pro- vide statistica­l evidence that competitiv­e parties are more likely to field wealthier candidates, and, even when focusing only on those candidates that have some chance of winning, wealth is strongly correlated to electoral success.

This result is consistent with growing incentives parties face to select wealthy candidates to self-finance increasing­ly expensive campaigns.

Self-financing candidates, in addition to covering their own campaign costs, can bring in funds for the party and subsidise poorer candidates.

The root cause of the rise of wealthy candidates is the weak representa­tive role of India’s elected politician­s. The rules governing the system are such that, even after winning election, legislator­s have little power in policymaki­ng— which is controlled by a small set of party elites. In short, India’s politician­s have little incentive to invest in actually becoming good representa­tives, and they are more likely to see the election as an economic investment in the future. It all adds up to a compromise­d democratic system in which the candidates for whom we vote need not represent our interests.

Sircar is a senior fellow at the Centre for Policy Research

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India