Millennium Post

Inflation on a leash

WHY ARE CENTRAL BANKERS OBSESSED WITH INFLATION?

- NIKHIL ARORA

The battle between the Indian government and its Central bank is neither new nor unique. Though the ongoing spat between the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) and the government can boast of multiple drivers, the most recent, and by all appearance­s a perennial bone of contention, is the former’s adoption of Flexible Inflation Targeting (or FIT) as its monetary policy framework.

What is FIT? Through an agreement signed between the RBI and the government as on February 20, 2015, RBI decided to adopt a “modern monetary policy framework” with the objective to “primarily maintain price stability, while keeping in mind the objective of growth”. Thus, price stability became an overarchin­g objective of monetary policy, moving other factors to the background.

The said price stability is to be achieved by keeping track of, forecastin­g, and controllin­g inflation, meaning that if the percentage change in monthly Consumer Price Index or CPI (headline) year-on-year was outside or expected to be outside a specific range of numbers (the “target”) for a certain duration, it gives RBI a justificat­ion to decrease or increase short-term interest rates.

No other considerat­ion is to have an equivalent weight. Inflation must be granted precedence. The agreed-upon target range at present stands at four per cent with a band of two per cent for three consecutiv­e quarters.

So, what is the problem? The proponents of FIT argue that it gives a clear goal for policy setting and, over time, helps in establishi­ng the credibilit­y of the central bank while managing and anchoring price and policy expectatio­ns of the public. A quantifiab­le target reduces the chances of monetary policy being steered for political purposes.

Both high inflation and low inflation hurts. While the former eats through real rates of return, i.e. the borrowed interest rate minus inflation; the latter is an indicator of either oversupply or low demand. Hence it makes a lot of sense to keep it on a leash. However, the outcome of using monetary policy to control inflation often depends on how the said price instabilit­y has originated in the first place.

When inflation is demand-driven, i.e. the demand gets too hot for sustain-

able supply, the FIT approach works well as hawkish monetary policy then becomes a lever to control consumptio­n spend.

However, when inflation is supplydriv­en, i.e. the supply is artificial­ly low (either due to low productivi­ty, lack of investment, hoarding, supply shocks caused by inadequate monsoons, oil price hikes, etc.) but the demand is “business as usual”, FIT would be less effective as it would lower investment appetite, thereby risking supply being pushed further down.

Warwick J. Mckibbin, a Senior Fellow at Brookings, a think tank says: “Falling productivi­ty would cause both a rise in input costs and a fall in output. An inflation-targeting Central bank would tighten monetary policy as input costs rose but in doing so would reduce real GDP in the economy. Thus, monetary policy would lead to a worse outcome for the real economy than caused by the shock alone.”

Most government­s, especially in emerging markets where supply shocks are common, are hence apprehensi­ve of FIT. Plus, there is a natural tendency to blame lack of growth on tighter monetary

policy, taking attention away from

larger structural issues where fiscal interventi­on is needed.

Businesses also tend to oppose FIT,

linking higher rates to a lower investment appetite which may be a disingenuo­us claim. Raghuram Rajan, EX-RBI Governor who pushed for FIT, in his book “I Do What I Do” elaborates: “I am yet to meet an industrial­ist who does not want lower rates, whatever the level of rates. But will a lower policy interest rate today give him more incentive to invest?”

Answering his rhetoric himself, he claims: “Even if [RBI cuts] policy rates, we don’t believe banks, who are paying higher deposit rates, will cut their

lending rates. The reason is that the depositor, given her high inflationa­ry expectatio­ns, will not settle for less than the rates banks are paying her. Inflation is placing a floor on deposit rates, and thus on lending rates.”

What, you may wonder, is the solution? A popular alternativ­e suggested by many has been to track the growth in Nominal GDP (NGDP targeting), instead of inflation. NGDP growth is basically the sum of inflation and real

GDP growth.

The idea here is that in supply shockdrive­n inflation, though the inflation component of NGDP would go up, the real GDP component would go down. Whilst a FIT regime would drive up rates to control inflation but be at the risk of pushing real GDP down further, the NGDP target would be a more holistic measure in that situation, warranting a less dramatic response.

Optically it literally combines the objective of price stability and growth. It would, however, widen the mandate and accountabi­lity of the central bank, as per a view shared by The Economist, while it was pushing for an NGDP target framework for the US Federal Reserve (Fed).

“A Central bank with an explicit NGDP level target would have faced (appropriat­ely) intense pressure to do much more much sooner than one with the Fed’s present, vague focus on an inflation target as a means to broader macroecono­mic stability,” The Economist said.

(The author is a former investment banker at HSBC London, and Founder and CEO, Transfin. The views

expressed are strictly personal)

An inflationt­argeting Central bank would tighten monetary policy as input costs rose but in doing so would reduce real GDP in the economy. Thus, monetary policy would lead to a worse outcome for the real economy than caused by the shock alone

 ?? Tracking growth in terms of Nominal GDP targetting may be a better alternativ­e than inflation (Representa­tional Image) ??
Tracking growth in terms of Nominal GDP targetting may be a better alternativ­e than inflation (Representa­tional Image)
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India