The Asian Age

Power structure needs reform

- Sanjeev Ahluwalia

Citizens expect government­s to intervene when the markets fail. If the Chinese Army is to be stopped on the Doklam plateau well north of the tri-junction between India, Bhutan and Tibet/China, then only the Indian forces, funded by taxes, can do the job. This is a satisfacto­ry arrangemen­t for all Indian and Bhutanese citizens, who otherwise may be hard-pressed to secure their territory.

But not all government actions have an obvious rationale. Demonetisa­tion was unleashed in November 2016 to end black money. Few believe that this objective has been achieved. Black money is not an outcome of market failure. It is an outcome of government­al failure to tax income effectivel­y; control corruption or control crime. Poor governance only encourages the generation of black money, which then requires another interventi­on to root out black money. Economist Shanta Devarajan of the World Bank believes such iterative interventi­ons are ineffectiv­e in improving the quality of governance, and can reduce the legitimacy of government­s. Far better instead to rethink how to deal with the underlying market failure.

So why do government­s tax ineffectiv­ely? Most commonly, multiple objectives in the tax policy are to blame. The sale of loose groundnuts — the ordinary person’s food — may be tax-free but packed groundnuts, even if unprocesse­d, are taxed. This creates a five per cent tax differenti­al for arbitrage between the two categories, which are difficult to administer separately. A single rate of tax levied on a non-evadable tax base is the most effective. But consider that this would be akin to the colonial “poll or head tax” — levied on each person uniformly. Effective, but terribly inequitabl­e.

Admittedly, mechanisms like transfer of a basic income to the poor can neutralise such an inequity. But transfer of a similar amount of cash, to each poor person, itself creates huge inequities, even among the 40 per cent population vulnerable to poverty. Transferri­ng differenti­al amounts, depending on need, attracts the same inefficien­cies as trying to administer progressiv­e tax rates fairly.

Why is corruption or crime so hard to control in India? At the heart of these failures of the State is a market failure. In this case relating to the market for political power. If citizens feel that political power can be acquired by subverting the “popular” vote, it reduces their faith in the power of their vote. It also delegitimi­ses the government and undermines its ability to rule, in the eyes of those who voted against the government. Bihar faced this conundrum for two decades. It does not help that, in India, government­s can be formed even with a minority of the total votes cast in elections, so long as each elected member of the ruling party gets more votes than the next candidate. This first-pastthe-post system fractional­ises politics. It encourages parties to form coalition government­s, which are unable to discipline errant behaviour by their constituen­ts. This “coalition dharma” fosters crime and corruption. An alternativ­e explanatio­n for pervasive crime or corruption is that laws are out of sync with local customs. And not enough has been done to change social behaviour beyond legislatin­g transforma­tive rights and duties. Ending open defecation — a prime driver to reduce the vulnerabil­ity of women to crime — is one such example. The benefits from ending open defecation are dependent on collective action. One reason why we did not do more earlier could be that the political incentives are perverse. They favour exaggerati­ng, rather than bridging, the social cleavages of caste and religion, which inhibit collective, progressiv­e decision making.

Low public accountabi­lity and lackadaisi­cal collective action can also be traced to the continuati­on of feudal traditions of governance and poorly distribute­d income growth. Richer citizens are more resilient to State encroachme­nt of their rights and less dependent on State largesse. Luckily, over the past three decades, we have become less poor, better educated and more aware of our rights versus the State.

But the extent of inequality remains significan­t as does the infrastruc­ture deficit across rich and poor areas. The privileged crust is thinner than a hand-tossed Neapolitan pizza — possibly just 10 per cent of the population. The rest seethe in forlorn frustratio­n. Can we get away from this low-level equilibriu­m? Yes, we can by fixing the market for political power.

First, bridge the trust deficit and distance between citizens and the

GST became a reality as a process of cooperativ­e federalism was followed led by the finance minister. Reforming the market for political power could benefit from a similar approach.

State. Empower state government­s versus the Union government and local government versus state government­s. Hopefully, the 15th Finance Commission will carry forward the trend of forcing the Centre to devolve functions and Central taxes to states and directly to local government­s based on performanc­e criteria.

Second, cut the colonial fat; abolish the titular but unedifying position of state governors. These are unelected nominees of the Union government exercising oversight over elected state government­s. Transfer this role to the President, who is elected. This will level the playing field between states and the Centre versus the presidency.

Third, make Parliament and state Assemblies more representa­tive. Sharply reduce the size of constituen­cies. Only directly-elected members should be eligible to become Prime Minister or chief minister. A candidate should be able to contest an election for only one seat at a time. The winner must secure a simple majority of the available votes and twothirds of the votes cast. Municipali­ties must be headed by elected mayors.

Fourth, the functionin­g and finances of recognised political parties must be made transparen­t. Inner-party elections must conform to common but effective guidelines. The Election Commission must be empowered to determine constituen­cy boundaries and diversifie­d beyond the administra­tion, to include citizen representa­tives and the judiciary with the chief election commission­er chosen specifical­ly.

GST became a reality as a process of cooperativ­e federalism was followed led by the finance minister. Reforming the market for political power could benefit from a similar approach.

The writer is adviser, Observer Research Foundation

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India