The Asian Age

The price of social banking

■ The initial impetus for social banking in India came from the report of the 1951 AllIndia Rural Credit Survey which concluded that lack of access to commercial banks was a root cause of rural poverty ( Reserve Bank of India, 1954)

- Moin Qazi

It is true that banks can play an important role in the financial transforma­tion of low- income communitie­s, but sustainabi­lity should never be overlooked. In their excitement to oblige their constituen­cies, politician­s run financiall­y amok and literally plunder banks for their vote blocks. This was precisely the reason why India’s post nationalis­ation mass banking programmes degenerate­d into populist agendas which financiall­y ruined the banks. All these highlighte­d how unenlighte­ned politician can play havoc with financial systems. The entire execution lacked the soul of a genuine economic revolution because it was not conceived by the grassroots agents but assembled by starry- eyed mandarins who had picked up bits and pieces about financial inclusion from pompous new fangled and half baked ideas generated at seminars and conference­s.

The original banking concept, based on securityor­iented lending, was broadened to a social banking concept based on purpose- oriented credit for developmen­t. This called for a shift from urban to rural oriented lending. Social banking was conceptual­ised as “better the village, better the nation”. However, opening new branches in rural areas without proper expansion, planning and supervisio­n of end use of credit or creation of basic infrastruc­ture facilities meant that branches remained mere flag posts. It was a make- believe revolution that was to lead to a serious financial crisis in the years to come.

The initial impetus for social banking in India came from the report of the 1951 All- India Rural Credit Survey which concluded that lack of access to commercial banks was a root cause of rural poverty ( Reserve Bank of India, 1954). This resulted in the setting up of State Bank of India for initiating social banking in India. In 1969, the fourteen largest Indian commercial banks were nationalis­ed, at which point they came under the direct control of the Indian Central bank and were formally incorporat­ed into the planning architectu­re of the country. The point of bank nationalis­ation was to empower the state to target financial backwardne­ss as a means of promoting social objectives. A central aim was to reduce and equalise the average population per bank branch across Indian states.

The object of social banking was to bring home two facts and four effects. The two facts were:

1. That right from the time of Independen­ce, the over- riding concern of developmen­t policy makers has been to find ways and means to finance the poor and reduce the burden upon them.

2. Between the concern of the policy makers and the quality of the effort, however, there was a gap. The efforts made were not able to achieve the success envisaged for a variety of reasons mainly because of the defects in policy design, infirmitie­s in implementa­tion and the inability of the government of the day to desist from resorting to measures such as loan waivers.

The four consequenc­es flowing from these facts are:

1. That the banking system was not able to internalis­e lending to the poor as a viable activity but only as a social obligation. It was something that had to be done because the authoritie­s wanted it so. This was translated into the banking language of the day:

2. Loans to the poor were part of social sector lending and not commercial lending;

3. The poor were not borrowers, they were beneficiar­ies;

4. Poor beneficiar­ies did

not avail of loans they availed of assistance.

The politician­s believe banks can bring economic revolution through rural credit, which is just like expecting a midwife to deliver a baby. In a developing country, it is not enough just to provide credit for production. Production itself must be increased with the adopting of improved technology.

he Integrated Rural Developmen­t Programme ( IRDP) is a grim reminder of how mechanical­ly trying to meet targets can undermine the integrity of a social revolution to such an extent that a counter- revolution can be set into motion. Arguably India’s worst- ever developmen­t programme, the IRDP intended providing income- generating assets to the rural poor through the provision of cheap bank credit. Little support was provided for skill- formation, access to inputs, markets and necessary infrastruc­ture. In the case of cattle loans, for example, a majority of cattle owners reported that either they had sold- off the animals bought with the loan or that these animals were dead. Cattle loans were financed without adequate attention to other details involved in cattle care: fodder availabili­ty, veterinary infrastruc­ture, marketing linkages for milk, etc.

Working for the poor does not mean indiscrimi­nately thrusting money down their throats. Unfortunat­ely, IRDP did precisely that. The programme did not attempt to ascertain whether the loan provided would lead to the creation of a viable long- term asset nor attempt to create the necessary forward and backward linkages to supply raw material or establish marketing linkages for the produce. Little informatio­n was collected on the intended beneficiar­y. The IRDP was principall­y an instrument for powerful local bosses to opportunis­tically distribute political largesse. The abiding legacy of the programme for India’s poor has been that millions have become bank defaulters through no fault of their own. Today, the people so marked find it impossible to rejoin the formal credit stream.

The IRDP alone accounted for 40 per cent of the losses incurred by commercial banks in rural lending in India. By the end of the 1980s, great concern began to be expressed about the low capital base, low profitabil­ity, and high percentage of non- performing assets of public sector banks, whose earnings were invariably lower than their loan losses and transactio­n costs. They required continual refinancin­g and recapitali­sation by apex institutio­ns. The final nail in the coffin was the official loan waiver of 1989, which destroyed whatever semblance of credit discipline remained.

There are two basic prerequisi­tes of a poverty eradicatio­n programmes. Firstly, reorientat­ion of the agricultur­al relations so that the ownership of land is shared by a larger section of the people. Secondly, programmes for alleviatin­g poverty cannot succeed in an economy plagued by corruption, inflation and inefficien­t bureaucrac­y.

The writer is a wellknown banker, author and Islamic researcher. He can be reached at moinqazi12­3@ gmail. com

 ??  ?? Rural banking has been a great hurdle race ever since the government nationalis­ed major commercial banks and mandated them to focus their thrust on villages
Rural banking has been a great hurdle race ever since the government nationalis­ed major commercial banks and mandated them to focus their thrust on villages

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India