The Free Press Journal

Reforms still ignore farmers’ plight in country

- The writer is an economist and Senior Fellow, Takshashil­a Institutio­n (Syndicate: The Billion Press) Ajit Ranade

India’s celebrated economic reforms of 1991 did lead to a substantia­l increase in economic growth, per-capita incomes, trade openness, stock of foreign exchange and deepening of the financial sector. The twin spectre of food and forex shortage no longer haunted India, although food self-sufficienc­y had been obtained much earlier due to the Green Revolution. There have been nine Parliament­s elected, and several government­s of different coalitions, since 1991. But even then, the direction of economic reforms has remained unchanged, if not the pace. There is of course much unfinished work, especially when it comes to job creation and the ease of doing business, with also newer challenges like climate change and worsening inequality.

There is however one area where economic reforms have failed to deliver, perhaps more by intent and not by oversight. That is the area of agricultur­e. The spirit of deregulati­on, delicensin­g, less government control, more free markets, has been absent, or pursued with very little enthusiasm when it comes to farm issues. Agricultur­e remains a protected and subsidised sector among most members of the World Trade Organisati­on. That does not mean it enjoys great prosperity. In the case of India, and perhaps few other emerging market economies, the farm sector receives net negative subsidy. It is thus penalised, and also not allowed to fully function as per free market principles. This is because of both, a historic legacy of special favourite treatment to industry and also due to the constant concern about food prices and inflation.

If you let free market reign, maybe food prices may skyrocket! Hence is the desire to “control” the forces that operate agricultur­e markets. In the past, as India pursued an import substituti­on-based industrial developmen­t model, agricultur­al prices were kept low, to help wage goods and industrial investment. But as if to compensate the farmer for price ceiling on his product, he was given input subsidies on fertiliser, credit, water and electricit­y. The input subsidies were invariably cornered by big farmers, so more controls were introduced. The cheap inputs also led to their overuse, and led to problems like salinity of land due to excessive usage of fertiliser, as in Punjab.

Another example is the food procuremen­t and Public Distributi­on Scheme. These were aimed to achieve three objectives with one instrument: that of food security, price stability and farm viability. It has been a partial success, since PDS offtake is very low in states with high poverty. In the past, it has also led to anomalous situations of high food stocks in government warehouses and also high food prices. Similarly, various rural developmen­t initiative­s have met with limited success, as is testified by the fact that the bulk of India’s poverty is still within rural areas and in agricultur­e.

There are of course structural challenges, which make India’s situation unique and difficult. Firstly, we have one of the worst land man ratios due to population. Besides, half the population is still stuck in agricultur­e or the rural economy. Secondly, land holdings are extremely fragmented, with very little forces of consolidat­ion. Thirdly, more than 85 percent of households have farm holdings of less than five acres, which means they suffer from inefficien­t scale. Fourthly, even now, more than half of all farmers do not have access to formal credit. They have to depend on friends, family or moneylende­rs. Fifth, moneylende­rs still operate in the shadows of illegitima­cy. They are often best equipped to assess the need of farmers, and also have ability to recover loans, or give extension. But moneylende­rs do not have the confidence of lawmakers. Sixth, is the issue of tenancy farming. This is the de facto practice, and almost one third of farming is done by leasing, a practice still not fully recognised in law. Besides, a tenant farmer cannot offer land as collateral, so access to formal credit is a problem. Seventh, the Commission for Agricultur­al Costs and Prices does not fully account for costs like self-labour, true cost of electricit­y and other services, logistics and high cost of finance from moneylende­rs. Hence the minimum support price (MSP) based on the Commission’s advice, fails to be viable. Eighth is the issue of supply chain. The road from farm to fork is long and full of obstacles. The price that a farmer gets for his produce can be as low as one-tenth of what is paid by the retail buyer in urban areas. How to ensure that a larger pie of this value goes to the farmer and not to other middlemen? This glaring inefficien­cy clearly points to the urgency of reform. One could go on. It is clear that due to a combinatio­n of structural challenges and policy myopia or neglect, the farm sector continues to suffer.

In recent years, and especially by the present government, there have been attempts to correct the situation of pending reforms in agricultur­e. So, removing the shackles of Agricultur­e Produce Marketing Committee (APMC) Act, reducing the role of intermedia­ries, introducti­on of an all-India market place, liberalise­d crop insurance are all examples of reforms. These are however inadequate, and much more needs to be done.

Farmers are so many and so diffused, operating under such diverse conditions nationwide, that they do not have a unified voice. Nor is there any vested interest (like industry chambers) which can be a potent force representi­ng them. Hence the dominant and main working principle ought to be “leave them alone”! The less the shackles of regulation on the farmer, the better. It is not that farmers “want something”, like guaranteed price or offtake, cheap or free electricit­y and credit and other freebies. If they can get fair market value for their labour and production, that would probably eliminate the need for much of the interventi­on by the government.

The recent episode of farm loan waivers across eight states once again brings the farm sector woes in focus. Loan waivers do not solve any of the issues highlighte­d above, but have become a political and moral imperative due to acute distress. It is hoped that in these waivers, genuine cases get adequate relief. But unless we undertake the reforms of truly unshacklin­g agricultur­e, we are simply biding time till the next crisis looms large again for farmers.

THE recent episode of farm loan waivers across eight states once again brings the farm sector woes in focus. Loan waivers do not solve any of the issues highlighte­d above, but have become a political and moral imperative due to acute distress. It is hoped that in these waivers, genuine cases get adequate relief.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India