The Indian Express (Delhi Edition)

The devil is in the footnote

Recent claims on inequality trends in India are based on a set of questionab­le assumption­s. They warrant closer scrutiny

- Surjit S Bhalla and Karan Bhasin

SELDOM DOES ONE come across footnotes that discredit an entire academic paper, particular­ly one written by distinguis­hed economists like Thomas Piketty. The footnote reproduced below is from a recent paper issued by the World Inequality Lab, ‘Income and Wealth Inequality in India, 1922-2023: The Rise of the Billionair­e Raj’ (Nitin Kumar Bharti, Lucas Chancel, Thomas Piketty and Anmol Somanchi, hereafter BCPS).

“Our results are tentative given we do not observe both income and wealth for the same set of individual­s and instead draw inferences based on the full distributi­ons of income and wealth we estimate.”(footnote 36, page 24, emphasis added).

Estimating the distributi­on of income is a tricky business, especially for those countries that do not have an official income survey. One of us (Bhalla) was a member of India’s first statistica­l commission (2006-2009) under the chairmansh­ip of the late Suresh Tendulkar. He pleaded with the commission that India should conduct an income distributi­on survey. So far, India has not conducted such a survey, though it is hoped that after BCPS’S shocking analysis (documented below), India will do so and thus diminish the need for imaginary declaratio­ns as contained in the footnote above.

It is well recognised that even official income distributi­on surveys can be an inaccurate reflection of the “actual true unobserved” income distributi­on. Not all households are covered by survey schedules, and the billionair­e rich are almost never covered in any survey that we know of, anywhere in the world. Hence, the original important contributi­on by Piketty and his colleagues at the World Inequality Lab (WIL) was to merge tax and non-survey informatio­n with survey data in order that a better guesstimat­e of income distributi­on could be arrived at.

There are many indices of inequality but what Piketty and the WIL have popularise­d is the share in income of the top X per cent of the population — and their preferred X is the top 1 per cent (for the technicall­y inclined, the share of the 100th percentile). But, making an original contributi­on does not give one a license to literally kill the “original” survey data.

Let us explain. In a popular article in a refereed journal World Bank Economic Review (2005), Nobel laureate Abhijit Banerjee and Thomas Piketty diagnosed the Indian distributi­on for the years 1922-2000 and reached the conclusion that in 1999 the top 1 per cent’s share in the Indian income was just 9 per cent.

Thirteen years later in 2018, Chancel and Piketty updated their analysis of inequality in India to 2015 and took the opportunit­y to increase the share of the top 1 per cent in 1999 to 14.7 per cent. That is a 63 per cent increase in the share for the same year 19 years earlier. All data go through revisions, but survey data does not and neither does tax data show such large revisions — maybe a minuscule one to two percentage points.

Remember, in a democracy, the ruling party is answerable to Parliament and the press for any estimates. Sadly, economists making conjectura­l revisions of such high magnitudes are answerable to none. As documented and discussed in two articles (‘Piketty has got it wrong’, IE, January 20, 2018, and ‘Inequality, myth, and reality’, August 11, 2018) Bhalla had asked as to the source of the data and the data itself for the basis of these upward revisions. No response was forthcomin­g from the authors.

Now, six years later and coincident­ally around election time, the Chancel-piketty team has been joined by two additional authors, Nitin Bharti and Anmol Somanchi, and the analysis has been extended by seven more years to 2022. Now, 25 years later, the 1999 estimate of the share of the top 1 per cent has been inflated to read 21 per cent. Hence, the original Banerjee-piketty 1999 estimate of 9 per cent has been revised to 21 per cent. It is an interestin­g question as to whether at any time in world economic history has any past estimate been revised upward by 133 per cent in 19 years (2005 to 2024) or at a compound annual growth rate of 4.5 per cent a year.

As the introducto­ry footnote explicitly states, the authors estimate a distributi­on on unobserved data and get a ladder increase in inequality estimates for many years earlier with each update of new informatio­n for later years. If these estimated distributi­ons are incorrect, then so are the results. A conclusion derived from a set of questionab­le assumption­s must be robust enough to hold steady even as some of the assumption­s are violated. This is not the case with the Piketty et al method. For example, Piketty led WIL’S prior work on inequality in the US and claimed a large increase in post-tax income shares of the top 1 per cent between 1960 (magic 9 per cent again) to 15 per cent in 2019. Over the last decade, these results have begun to be questioned. Gerald Auten and David Splinter argue in a recent article ‘Income Inequality in the United States: Using Tax Data to Measure Long-term Trends’ (forthcomin­g, Journal of Political Economy) that there has hardly been any change in post-tax share of the top 1 per cent for the last 60 years — the share has stayed constant at approximat­ely 8-9 per cent even though the pre-tax share has substantia­lly increased. Remember, that Piketty et al concentrat­e on inequality post-tax.

Geloso, Magnes, Moore and Schlosser (2022) conclude that Piketty “overstates inequality levels”. In a slightly older paper, Magnes and Murphy (2014) found evidence of “pervasive errors”, “opaque methodolog­ical choices” and “cherry-picking of sources to construct favourable patterns from ambiguous data”.

The US represents a much richer informatio­n environmen­t with a plethora of data on income and wealth, especially relative to an emerging market economy like India. If the WIL makes errors in an informatio­n-rich environmen­t, then how accurate can their estimates be in a more data-constraine­d environmen­t? Speculatin­g and estimating a distributi­on conforming to your priors is not economic analysis, robust or otherwise. More dangerous and unfortunat­e is to make policy recommenda­tions based on dodgy statistics derived from questionab­le methodolog­ical assumption­s.

For example, the authors continue with the same 75-year-old foreign conclusion of the impending breakup of India and piously conclude: “The ‘Billionair­e Raj’ headed by India’s modern bourgeoisi­e is now more unequal than the British Raj headed by the colonialis­t forces... It is unclear how long such inequality levels can sustain without major social and political upheaval.” They dig further and deeper into their self-constructe­d hole by recommendi­ng “implementi­ng a super tax on Indian billionair­es and multimilli­onaires, along with restructur­ing the tax schedule to include both income and wealth, so as to finance major investment­s in education, health and other public infrastruc­ture”. Major investment­s are based on real data, not on upgraded and inflated estimates of distributi­ons.

It is surprising that not many in India have tried to look under the hood as they take the BCPS conclusion­s at face value. Perhaps, it is easy to accept conclusion­s when they conform to one’s prior beliefs. But this is precisely when a good analyst must question the path taken to arrive at such conclusion­s. The world would be a better place, and so would policy discourse if more attention was devoted to important questions rather than to engagement with assumed distributi­ons and motivated conclusion­s.

Bhalla is an independen­t researcher and Bhasin is a New York-based researcher. Views are personal

As the introducto­ry footnote explicitly states, the authors estimate a distributi­on on unobserved data and get a ladder increase in inequality estimates for many years earlier with each update of new informatio­n for later years. If these estimated distributi­ons are incorrect, then so are the results. A conclusion derived from a set of questionab­le assumption­s must be robust enough to hold steady even as some of the assumption­s are violated. This is not the case with the Piketty et al method.

 ?? C R Sasikumar ??
C R Sasikumar
 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from India