Sunday Independent (Ireland)

Coming to terms with the economic necessity of a V-word culture: after all, it’s a dirty job — but somebody’s got to do it

Vulture funds and culture capitalist­s have been getting a bad press for many years now, writes Declan Black. But let’s get real and accept the necessity of what it is they do

- Declan Black is managing partner at Mason Hayes & Curran. You can contact them at www.mhc.ie

VULTURES may be ugly birds — but they perform a useful service. They are one of nature’s recyclers and help the ecosystem by taking away the dead and unhealthy. It’s a dirty job, and one which can be distressin­g to witness — but it is a job which benefits the environmen­t as a whole.

These birds have lent their names to the label of ‘vulture funds’, which has since passed into the Irish lexicon as a pejorative term.

The label is used fairly indiscrimi­nately, and in my view often generates a negative emotional context which hinders fair assessment and obscures what is actually happening.

The demonising of so-called vulture funds ignores the fact that one of the key factors in Ireland’s recovery from the financial crisis was the willingnes­s of foreign private equity — particular­ly US private equity — to invest in Ireland.

Much of that investment was in so-called ‘distressed assets’ — usually meaning either under-performing loans with their associated security, or real estate assets held by entities which did not have the financial wherewitha­l to fully utilise such assets.

The position in Ireland during the crisis was that the banks had to reduce their balance sheets and address the problem of nonperform­ing loans. To a considerab­le extent, this remains the position today.

The choices with non-performing loans are few: (1) appoint receivers or otherwise take possession of the secured assets or (2) sell the loans and associated security to third parties.

For an institutio­n which has long-term ambitions to remain and build in a market, option one is both difficult to execute and it carries risk.

Piecemeal repossessi­ons and sales carry high transactio­nal costs. Suing borrowers is expensive and the cash return is usually low. Both activities hurt the reputation of the institutio­n.

A policy of soft deals with some borrowers carries contagion risk for other borrowers, makes future lending riskier (and therefore more expensive for borrowers) and is perceived by compliant borrowers as simply unfair. Therefore, it is not surprising that option two is popular with institutio­ns.

Happily for Ireland, option two became feasible. There were buyers for underperfo­rming loans — and a market developed.

The effect of this market on the Irish economy and Irish society has been broadly beneficial. While in legal terms, the buyers purchased loans and related security, in value terms they usually only wanted and priced the security. This security was usually comprised of commercial or residentia­l real estate. The emergence of this market was key to the recovery in real estate prices. This, on a corporate level, helped stabilise the financial position of the banks and helped Nama generate returns for the Exchequer. On a societal level, it reduced negative equity and contribute­d to positive equity, thereby generating confidence — which in turn leads to consumer spending. Overall, a positive cycle was created. For commercial real estate, the removal of such

assets from entities which could not exploit or develop them because of their financial situation, and the transfer of such assets to entities which could do so because they have the necessary resources, is clearly good for the economy.

Productive and well-exploited assets create wealth and jobs. Moribund assets don’t. And the faster you can shift assets from being moribund to being productive and exploited, the faster the economic benefit comes.

From an economic standpoint, people are key assets too — and again the economy benefits from more people being engaged and productive.

Many commentato­rs have flagged the detrimenta­l economic effect of having so many people burdened by debt which they have little prospect of repaying.

They can become disengaged and demotivate­d because there is little incentive to work to create wealth when you have to use any wealth that is created to pay off old debt.

The so-called vultures have had a broadly positive effect here too.

Unhindered by a fear of contagion, and not having substantia­l current and future lending to protect, the funds have proved both quick and willing to do deals with borrowers.

That they generally do this without recourse to the courts is clear from an examinatio­n of the court records.

Therefore, not only are physical assets better utilised in the economy because they become owned by a party with resources to exploit them — but individual­s and companies have their residual debt obligation­s reduced to manageable proportion­s (or waived), and accordingl­y are themselves in turn better motivated and better able to contribute to the economy.

It is of course true that the observatio­ns made above are points of broad applicatio­n.

They deliberate­ly ignore the individual stories of hardship and failure which feature in every downturn.

This is not because these stories don’t matter: far from it. It is because a recovering economy which supports the rapid recycling of assets means we should have fewer such stories and at least the prospect of a happier ending for some.

The problem with individual stories is that we tend to brand the actors as heroes or villains — and these character roles are too easily filled by the archetypal downtrodde­n small businessma­n and the faceless vulture fund.

Thematic stories don’t have heroes and villains and are complex. But proper analysis should be concerned with broad and thematic effects.

It is only populist and Trump-like analysis which is dominated by simplistic stories of heroes and villains.

So what should this mean in policy terms for our new Government?

First, please do not speak of engenderin­g an entreprene­urial spirit or “celebratin­g failure” if you are not prepared to accept that entreprene­urial activity — such as investment in distressed assets — also results in immediatel­y visible casualties in terms of business failures and lost jobs.

You must trust that more viable businesses and more sustainabl­e jobs will emerge.

Second, policies which accept business failure as an intrinsic part of a capitalist system but — crucially — which promote the efficient and quick recycling of assets from business failure should generate more wealth, more business and more employment than policies which are aimed at preserving existing businesses and existing jobs.

So please don’t jam up the insolvency processes or you will have moribund assets for longer.

Third, don’t adopt populist policies based on hard personal histories.

Just as hard cases make bad law, policies which originate from hard personal histories can have very detrimenta­l broad effects.

If we adopted policies which undermined investor appetite, this would be more likely to have an overall regressive effect and perpetuate an environmen­t where hard personal histories will continue and proliferat­e.

Lastly, this does not mean we should have a capitalist free-for-all. Of course there should be safeguards and a safety net. And of course there should be regulation.

But the regulation needs to be proportion­ate and it needs to be firmly focused on the overall climate it is intended to create. And that is a climate where even vultures can do their work.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Ireland