Jamaica Gleaner

Schrödinge­r’s bitcoin

- GUEST COLUMNIST Willem H. Buiter is Visiting Professor of Internatio­nal and Public Affairs at Columbia University. © Project Syndicate, 2021 www.project-syndicate.org

ON FEBRUARY 8, Elon Musk’s electric-car firm Tesla announced that it had invested US$1.5 billion of its cash reserves in bitcoin back in January.

The news helped to boost the cryptocurr­ency’s already skyrocketi­ng price by a further 10 per cent, to a record high of more than US$44,000. But, especially in bitcoin’s case, what goes up can just as easily come crashing down.

Bitcoin was invented in 2008 and began trading in 2009. In 2010, the value of a single bitcoin rose from around eighthundr­edths of a cent to eight cents. In April 2011, it traded at 67 cents, before subsequent­ly climbing to US$327 by November 2015. As recently as March 20 last year, bitcoin traded at about US$6,200, but its price has since increased more than sevenfold.

Today, bitcoin is a perfect, 12-year-old bubble. I once described gold as “shiny bitcoin”, and characteri­sed the metal’s price as a 6,000-year-old bubble. That was a bit unfair to gold, which used to have intrinsic value as an industrial commodity (now largely redundant), and still does as a consumer durable widely used in jewellery.

Bitcoin, by contrast, has no intrinsic value; it never did and never will. It is a purely speculativ­e asset – a private fiat currency – whose value is whatever the markets say it is.

But bitcoin is also a socially wasteful speculativ­e asset, because it is expensive to produce. The cost of ‘mining’ an additional bitcoin – solving computatio­nal puzzles using energy-intensive digital equipment – increases at such a rate that the total stock of the cryptocurr­ency is

capped at 21 million units.

Of course, even if bitcoin’s protocol is not changed to allow for a larger supply, the whole exercise can be repeated through the issuance of bitcoin 2, bitcoin 3, and so on. The real costs of mining will thus be replicated, too. Moreover, there are already well-establishe­d cryptocurr­encies

– for example, ether – operating in parallel with bitcoin.

But as the success of government­issued fiat currencies shows, the universe of speculativ­e bubbles is by no means restricted to cryptocurr­encies like bitcoin. After all, in a world with flexible prices, there is always an equilibriu­m

where everyone believes the official fiat currency has no value – in which case it consequent­ly has no value. And there are infinitely many ‘non-fundamenta­l’ equilibria where the general price level – the reciprocal of the fiat currency’s price – either explodes and goes to infinity or implodes and falls to zero, even when the money stock remains fairly steady or does not change at all.

Finally, there is the unique ‘fundamenta­l equilibriu­m at which the price level (and the value of the currency) is positive and neither explodes nor implodes. Most government-issued fiat currencies appear to have stumbled into this fundamenta­l equilibriu­m and stayed there.

Keynesians ignore these multiple equilibria, viewing the price level – and thus the price of money – as uniquely determined by history and updated gradually through a mechanism like the Phillips curve, which posits a stable and inverse relationsh­ip between (unexpected) inflation and unemployme­nt.

Regardless of which perspectiv­e one adopts, real-world hyperinfla­tions – think of Weimar Germany or the recent cases of Venezuela and Zimbabwe – that effectivel­y reduce the value of money to zero are examples not of non-fundamenta­l equilibria, but rather of fundamenta­l equilibria gone bad. In these cases, money stocks exploded, and the price level responded accordingl­y.

Private cryptocurr­encies and public fiat currencies have the same infinite range of possible equilibria. The zero-price equilibriu­m is always a possibilit­y, as is the unique, wellbehave­d fundamenta­l equilibriu­m.

Bitcoin clearly is exhibiting neither of these equilibria at the moment. What we have instead appears to be a variant of a non-fundamenta­l explosive price equilibriu­m. It is a variant because it must allow for bitcoin to make a possible, if unexpected, jump from its current explosive price trajectory to either the nice fundamenta­l equilibriu­m or the notso-nice zero-price scenario. This multipleeq­uilibrium perspectiv­e doubtless makes it appear risky to invest in intrinsica­lly valueless assets like bitcoin and other private cryptocurr­encies.

The real world is of course not constraine­d by the range of possible equilibria supported by the mainstream economic theory outlined here. But that makes bitcoin even riskier as an investment.

Tesla’s recent bitcoin buy-in shows that a large additional buyer entering the market can boost the cryptocurr­ency’s price significan­tly, both directly when markets are illiquid, and indirectly through demonstrat­ion and emulation effects. But an exit by a single important player would likely have a similar impact in the opposite direction. Positive or negative opinions voiced by market makers will have significan­t effects on bitcoin’s price.

The cryptocurr­ency’s spectacula­r price volatility is not surprising. Deeply irrational market gyrations like the one that drove GameStop’s share price to unpreceden­ted highs in January – followed by a significan­t correction – should serve as a reminder that, lacking any obvious fundamenta­l value anchor, bitcoin is likely to remain a textbook example of excess volatility. This will not change with time. Bitcoin will continue to be an asset without intrinsic value whose market value can be anything or nothing. Only those with healthy risk appetites and a robust capacity to absorb losses should consider investing in it.

 ??  ?? Tesla CEO Elon Musk speaks next to a Tesla vehicle. Musk has said his company will soon start accepting payment in bitcoin.
Tesla CEO Elon Musk speaks next to a Tesla vehicle. Musk has said his company will soon start accepting payment in bitcoin.
 ??  ?? A graphical representa­tion of bitcoins.
A graphical representa­tion of bitcoins.
 ??  ?? Willem Buiter
Willem Buiter

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Jamaica