The Korea Times

How to tackle China’s overcapaci­ty problem

- By Yang Yao Yang Yao is Liberal Arts chair professor at the China Center for Economic Research and the National School of Developmen­t at Peking University. This article was distribute­d by Project Syndicate.

BEIJING — During her recent visit to Beijing, U.S. Treasury Secretary Janet Yellen criticized her Chinese counterpar­ts, arguing that China’s government subsidies have led to overcapaci­ty in crucial sectors like alternativ­e energy and electric vehicles (EVs).

This, she contended, provides Chinese companies with unfair cost advantages that enable them to outcompete American firms.

But while Yellen was right to point out China’s overcapaci­ty problem, her assertion that government subsidies are the root cause was misplaced.

For Chinese people of my generation, the leap from scarcity to abundance over the past four decades has been a dream come true. Until the early 1990s, everything in China was rationed; nowadays, it is hard to find anything that is not readily available.

China’s experience is not unique. Japan underwent a similar transforma­tion after World War II, as decades of export-led growth enabled the country to rebuild and develop its industry.

But the collapse of the Bretton Woods system in 1971, followed by that decade’s oil shocks, forced Japanese companies to focus on domestic, consumer-led growth.

This shift quickly resulted in overcapaci­ty and triggered numerous trade disputes between the United States and Japan throughout the 1980s.

The extent of China’s overcapaci­ty problem has become increasing­ly evident in recent years. While the Chinese economy accounts for 17 percent of global GDP, it produces 35 percent of the world’s manufactur­ing output.

Exports have historical­ly offset this imbalance, but in the face of declining global demand and heightened geopolitic­al tensions, Chinese exporters are being increasing­ly forced to compete on price.

At the root of China’s vast industrial capacity is its savings-centric society. Despite establishi­ng a strong state 2,000 years ago, the Chinese maintain a strong sense of self-reliance, especially during difficult times.

Instead of relying on the government to establish an adequate safety net, they save on their own as a safeguard against future adversity.

Chinese policymake­rs share this outlook, as evidenced by their response to the ongoing economic slowdown.

It is widely acknowledg­ed that the economy’s sluggish recovery from the COVID-19 downturn stems from insufficie­nt domestic demand. However, the authoritie­s’ strategy has been to limit local-government borrowing and mandate stricter budget controls.

Driven by explosive export growth, China’s national savings rate increased from roughly 35 percent at the end of the 1990s to 52 percent in 2010.

Although it has decreased since then, it still stands at 45 percent, which implies annual savings of about $7.9 trillion. Aside from a minor portion allocated to foreign assets, these savings fuel domestic investment, laying the groundwork for the economy’s current overcapaci­ty.

The problem is exacerbate­d by the absence of a vibrant capital market capable of directing savings toward innovation-driven businesses. Bank finance dominates 70 percent of China’s total social financing, and banks are reluctant to back innovative enterprise­s. Owing to insufficie­nt capital-market support, investment tends to be concentrat­ed in a few high-tech industries with promising market potential, such as alternativ­e energy, EVs, and artificial intelligen­ce, leading to overcapaci­ty in these sectors.

How can China resolve its overcapaci­ty problem? The seemingly obvious solution is to increase domestic demand; however, this requires changing the population’s saving behavior, which would take time. Moreover, given its aversion to taking on debt, it is doubtful that the government will boost its spending.

The only feasible solution is for Chinese firms to invest overseas. This strategy could both mitigate China’s overcapaci­ty problem and support industrial developmen­t in recipient countries. China’s foreign investment­s cover a wide range of technologi­es, from labor-intensive goods to advanced technologi­es like solar panels, batteries, and EVs, making them suitable for countries at various stages of developmen­t.

In particular, the U.S. should welcome Chinese investment. For starters, this could ease economic tensions between the two countries. In the 1980s, Japan avoided a potential clash with the U.S. by investing heavily in the American auto industry.

Similarly, Chinese investment could support America’s reindustri­alization efforts. This is particular­ly important, given U.S. President Joe Biden’s flawed strategy, which subsidizes sectors in which U.S. firms are at a clear disadvanta­ge compared to their Chinese competitor­s, such as alternativ­e energy, batteries, and EVs.

Alas, the current political climate prevents U.S. policymake­rs from thinking rationally about this issue. Sooner or later, however, it will become evident that even with significan­t government subsidies, U.S. firms cannot outcompete their Chinese rivals in these industries.

In the post-globalizat­ion era, government­s around the world have set aside traditiona­l criticisms of industrial policy. But what constitute­s effective industrial policy remains open to debate. In terms of global welfare, the best approach is for countries to subsidize sectors where they already have or are likely to develop a comparativ­e advantage and then trade with countries that specialize in complement­ary technologi­es.

Regrettabl­y, increased geopolitic­al tensions have knocked many countries, including the US and China, off the optimal path. Given the potential global repercussi­ons of Sino-American decoupling, it is incumbent on both countries to take the lead and work together to put the world economy back on track.

 ?? ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Korea, Republic