Executive Magazine

Lebanon’s fiscal conundrum

What would make a good deal for Lebanon?

- Mona Sukkarieh is the cofounder of Middle East Strategic Perspectiv­es (http://www.mesp.me), a Beirut based political risk consultanc­y

22

There are two arguments being made today. Both agree the state should maximize its share of benefit, though they do not agree on what is the maximum benefit achievable. Some aim for a bid round that is as competitiv­e as more comparable bid rounds—while others demand a greater level of state participat­ion.

While it is commendabl­e to stand up for Lebanon’s rights, we would all be well advised to avoid misinforme­d populism. To put it simply, arguing Lebanon deserves a fair share implies the existence of a “share.” This share can only exist if the state contracts partners to explore for and produce potential resources. There are two parties to the deal; the terms must be attractive enough for both sides to commit to signing a contract. If no contract is signed the “share” vanishes, given the absence of indigenous capacity to conduct upstream operations.

Contrary to some claims, perpetuate­d by a political class that is struggling to manage expectatio­ns, current market conditions are unfavorabl­e for Lebanon. The country’s offshore area is mostly deep and ultradeep waters. Low oil prices since late 2014 means expensive exploratio­n in Lebanese waters is unattracti­ve at the moment. Companies must actually be persuaded to bid by Lebanon offering attractive fiscal terms.

Opponents of how Lebanon is conducting its first licensing round argue: (1) the model exploratio­n and production sharing contract decree is in conflict with the 2010 offshore oil and gas law as it prevents the state from participat­ing in the tender, distorting the system from an originally-intended production-sharing model to a profit-sharing model; and (2) the royalties and taxes, set out in the contract degree and tax law, are too low compared to a “global average.”

In fact, the 2010 offshore law explicitly says the Council of Ministers may establish a National Oil Company (NOC) “when necessary” but only “after promising commercial opportunit­ies have been verified,” which rules out an NOC in the first licensing round as this cannot be verified ahead of exploratio­n. Moreover, the state retains ownership of resources in the ground and a share of the produced hydrocarbo­ns once the company recovers capital and operationa­l expenditur­es, meaning Lebanon’s chosen model contract is a classic production-sharing system. The distinctio­n some wish to establish between a production-sharing model and a profit-sharing model is non-existent.

As for the fiscal terms, comparing them to a “global average” may seem to lend an air of seriousnes­s and profession­alism, but in reality, it is closer to comparing apples to oranges given the diverse range of countries with oil and gas resources. These countries include legacy producers with resources located in a variety of environmen­ts and other aspiring producers. One cannot compare a country with proven reserves to a country where drilling has not yet begun. Similarly, one cannot compare countries or provinces where exploratio­n is relatively cheap and easy to countries or provinces where it is expensive and complex. Finally, one cannot ignore Lebanon’s political risk, especially considerin­g the country’s first licensing round is now slated to close more than four years behind its original schedule. These are all elements that affect how attractive a country is to foreign companies. One way to compensate for Lebanon’s relative disadvanta­ge (i.e., no proven reserves in both a high-cost drilling and high-risk political environmen­t) is offering attractive terms for potential investors.

A more coherent approach would entail identifyin­g a group of countries or provinces with similar basins (deep-water offshore, and a more or less comparable status—early exploratio­n or production activity). Ideally, we would also add other elements: A local market that is comparable in size and the existence of little or no export infrastruc­ture, in addition to the sociopolit­ical environmen­t. By comparing Lebanon to a “global average,” those making this argument have steered the discussion toward unreasonab­le demands and inflated expectatio­ns.

Future licensing rounds will not necessaril­y be governed by the exact same legal framework. Future exploratio­n and production-sharing agreements (and the royalties included in them) will not necessaril­y be the same. Fiscal terms are not set in stone. Though regulatory stability is important, they may change in the future to adapt to new realities. Realism is key, whether now or in the future.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Lebanon