The Sun (Malaysia)

1997 Asian Crisis lessons lost

- By

AFTER months of withstandi­ng speculativ­e attacks on its national currency, the Thai central bank let it “float” on July 2, 1997, allowing its exchange rate to drop suddenly. Soon, currencies and stock markets throughout the region came under pressure as easily reversible short-term capital inflows took flight in herd-like fashion. By mid-July 1997, the currencies of Indonesia, Malaysia and the Philippine­s had also fallen precipitou­sly after being floated, with stock market price indices following suit.

Most other economies in East Asia were also under considerab­le pressure. In November 1997, despite South Korea’s more industrial­ised economy, its currency also collapsed following withdrawal of official support. Devaluatio­n pressures also mounted due to the desire to maintain a competitiv­e cost advantage against the devalued currencies of Southeast Asian exporters.

BLIND SPOT

Mainstream or orthodox economists first attempted to explain the unexpected events from mid-1997 in terms of orthodox theories of currency crisis. Many made much of current account or fiscal deficits, real as well as imagined.

When the convention­al wisdom clearly proved to be unconvinci­ng, the East Asian miracle was turned on its head. Instead, previously celebrated elements of the regional experience, eg, government interventi­ons and “social capital”, were blamed for the crises.

The media emphasised “cronyism”, ie, government favouritis­m for particular business interests, and poor corporate governance. These were real problems, but irrelevant to explaining the crisis. Increasing­ly, blame was put on poor sequencing of financial liberalisa­tion, but not on capital account liberalisa­tion itself.

This blind spot has helped ensure that the most important lessons from the crisis have been largely lost. Other currency and financial crises from the 1990s make clear that key lessons have not been appreciate­d. Instead, erroneous lessons drawn by orthodox economists, financial analysts and the media have muddied the policy discourse. Also, the policies and policymake­rs responsibl­e for the crisis need to be identified and addressed as they have come back, albeit in different guises.

Wrong lessons have diverted attention away from the intellectu­al and ideologica­l bases of the erroneous thinking, analyses and policies responsibl­e for the crises. Such ideas are largely, though not exclusivel­y associated with Washington Consensus’ advocacy of economic liberalisa­tion at both national and global levels. Thus, drawing critical lessons would undermine the intellectu­al, analytical and policy authority of the interests and institutio­ns involved.

FINANCE RULES

Although there was analytical work critical of East Asia’s “miracle” before the crisis, none actually anticipate­d the debacle or saw its roots in financial liberalisa­tion. Meanwhile, transnatio­nal dominance of industry in Southeast Asia facilitate­d the ascendance and consolidat­ion of financial interests and politicall­y influentia­l rentiers, later deemed “cronies” after 1997.

This increasing­ly powerful alliance successful­ly promoted financial liberalisa­tion in the region, both externally and internally. Southeast Asian financiers were quick to identify and capture rents from arbitrage and other opportunit­ies offered by internatio­nal financial integratio­n. Little caution was urged in the face of greater foreign capital flows in Southeast Asia, which became more pronounced in the 1990s.

Washington Consensus policy advocacy of financial liberalisa­tion from the 1980s had uneven consequenc­es and implicatio­ns for the region. This eventually led to new kinds of currency and financial crises due to easily reversed capital inflows, including foreign bank borrowings and portfolio capital flows.

As the interests of domestic financial capital did not fully coincide with those of internatio­nal finance, the impact of financial globalisat­ion was partial and uneven. For instance, both Malaysia and Thailand wanted capital inflows to finance current account deficits. This was largely due to their service account deficits, mainly for imported services and investment income payments abroad. Such deficits grew with imports for consumptio­n and constructi­on, as well as greater ease of investment, including speculatio­n, abroad.

There is no evidence that such capital inflows contribute­d significan­tly to accelerati­ng the growth of export earnings. Instead, they blew up asset price bubbles, which inevitably burst with devastatin­g economic, social and political consequenc­es.

LESSONS NOT LEARNT

Two decades later, there is apparently still no consensus on the East Asian crises and their causes. But contrary to the impression conveyed by the Western media, most serious analysts now agree that the crises essentiall­y began as currency crises of a new type, different from those previously identified with current account deficits, or fiscal profligacy, or even macroecono­mic indiscipli­ne more generally.

They also agree that the crises started off as currency crises and quickly became more generalise­d financial crises, before affecting the real economy. Reduced financial liquidity, inappropri­ate official policy responses and ill-informed, “herd”-like market responses then exacerbate­d this chain of events. – IPS

Comments: letters@thesundail­y.com

 ??  ?? From currency crisis to financial crisis, and then the real economy was affected.
From currency crisis to financial crisis, and then the real economy was affected.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Malaysia