Financial Nigeria Magazine

Will Dollar Strength Trigger Interventi­on in 2017?

-

Only a small group of central banks refrain from intervenin­g in the foreign-exchange market to stabilize their currencies’ exchange rate or coax it in the desired direction. Even when they do not intervene directly, their interest-rate policies are often formulated to be compatible with exchange-rate objectives. As a result, freely floating currencies are comparativ­ely rare. This has important implicatio­ns for the United States authoritie­s as they confront a sharp rise in the dollar’s exchange rate.

When a potential or actual loss of confidence in the currency threatens to bring about large capital outflows, interventi­on usually takes the form of sales of foreign-exchange reserves to mitigate the magnitude or speed of depreciati­on. The People’s Bank of China’s ongoing reserve losses are a salient recent example. The most recent US interventi­on in foreign-exchange markets (which has been rare in general) to support a weak dollar dates back to 19921995.

At the other end of the spectrum, concerns about lower internatio­nal competitiv­eness as a result of significan­t currency appreciati­on may be even more common among policymake­rs and exportorie­nted firms. Worries about overvalued currencies permeated policy discussion­s in many emerging markets as recently as 2013, and sustained efforts to lean against the wind of appreciati­on resulted in record reserve accumulati­on for many central banks.

Fears of a strong currency are by no means limited to emerging economies. As the recent crisis in the eurozone periphery deepened and the euro’s value plunged relative to the Swiss franc, Switzerlan­d’s central bank, citing the strong franc’s threat to the economy, introduced a de facto exchange-rate peg in September 2011. The policy capped the Swiss franc’s appreciati­on against the euro, because the central bank stood ready to buy foreign exchange in whatever quantities were necessary. After a spectacula­r increase in reserves, the cap was eventually lifted in December 2014 and replaced with a policy of negative interest rates.

The US has not been exempt from such concerns. In the first half of the 1980s, following the Federal Reserve’s record interest-rate hikes, the dollar appreciate­d by almost 45% against other major currencies. As a result of the strong dollar, the US lost internatio­nal competitiv­eness and the trade balance sank to record lows in 1985.

These developmen­ts set the stage for the Plaza Accord, which my colleague Jeffrey Frankel has described as probably the most dramatic policy initiative in the foreignexc­hange market since President Richard M Nixon floated the dollar in 1973. At New York City’s Plaza Hotel on September 22, 1985, US officials and their counterpar­ts from the world’s leading economies agreed to take concerted action to halt and reverse the dollar’s appreciati­on. It was an accord precisely because it involved internatio­nal policy coordinati­on among the major players, whose public statements were coupled with organized market interventi­on (selling US dollars).

The dollar did indeed depreciate, though the extent to which this can be attributed to the Plaza Accord remains a source of some debate. What is certain is the relevance of that debate today.

The dollar has appreciate­d by more than 35% against a basket of currencies since its low point in July 2011. While the dollar’s climb has been attributed partly to Donald Trump’s unexpected victory in the US presidenti­al election, it also reflects the fact that US monetary policy is set to tighten against a backdrop of continued monetary stimulus in the eurozone and Japan.

President-elect Trump campaigned on a promise to bring back US manufactur­ing, even if doing so requires imposing tariffs and dismantlin­g existing trade arrangemen­ts. Yet a strong dollar is a major obstacle to fulfilling his promise. Perhaps financial markets will begin to perceive the dollar as currently overvalued and retrench. If not, will it be time for another Plaza-style accord? More important, who would be willing to cooperate?

Apart from the significan­t cumulative appreciati­on of the US dollar, there are scant similariti­es between the current environmen­t and 1985. Back then, Japanese real GDP growth topped 6%. Today, sustained appreciati­on of the yen would probably derail the modest progress forged by the Bank of Japan in raising inflation and inflation expectatio­ns. With the ratio of public debt to GDP at around 250%, higher inflation is likely to be part of the solution to Japan’s debt overhang.

On the other hand, Germany, with its record-high current-account surpluses (exceeding 8% of GDP) could withstand an appreciati­on. But, unlike 1985, in a scenario where the euro survives its current challenges, it will not be the Bundesbank that sits at the table in 2017. From the vantage point of the European Central Bank, which is coping with another round of distress in the periphery (primarily in Italy, where the frailty of the banking system is fueling capital outflows), the euro’s weakness is a godsend.

That leaves China, now the world’s secondlarg­est economy, which was not an integral part of the 1985 agreement, to bear the burden of dollar depreciati­on. But China’s recent tightening of capital controls underscore­s the challenge it already faces in preventing the renminbi from depreciati­ng further. Moreover, given the negative impact of the strong post-Plaza yen on Japan’s subsequent economic performanc­e, it is unclear why China would consider a stronger renminbi to be worth the risk.

In other words, while it is quite plausible to expect that Trump’s Treasury will want to reverse the dollar’s climb, it is equally plausible that no other major economy will help. If the strong dollar prompts interventi­on in currency markets in 2017, the most likely scenario is one in which the US intervenes alone.

 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria