Financial Nigeria Magazine

Europe’s Hamiltonia­n moment

-

The new Franco-German proposal for a €500 billion ($547 billion) European recovery fund could turn out to be the most important historic consequenc­e of the coronaviru­s. It is even conceivabl­e that the deal struck between German Chancellor Angela Merkel and French President Emmanuel Macron might one day be remembered as the European Union’s “Hamiltonia­n moment,” comparable to the 1790 agreement between Alexander Hamilton and Thomas Jefferson on public borrowing, which helped to turn the United States, a confederat­ion with little central government, into a genuine political federation.

Admittedly, this sounds hyperbolic. The proposed sum for the recovery fund is small change in an era when politician­s and central bankers conjure up trillions almost daily. And what about the gulf between words and action throughout the EU’s history? Scepticism about the Franco-German proposal is certainly understand­able and may prove justified.

The plan amounts to only 3% of the EU’s GDP, compared with the 15% of GDP already committed by Germany to industrial support. Creating any EU recovery plan will require unanimous support from the EU’s 27 member countries – and this will involve unseemly late-night squabbles between the selfstyled “Frugal Four” northern government­s (the Netherland­s, Austria, Finland, and Sweden), which have vehemently opposed funding for

Mediterran­ean EU members which, according to Wopke Hoekstra, the Dutch Finance Minister, have mainly themselves to blame for “failing to reform.”

But to focus on these drawbacks is to miss the potential significan­ce of the plan. What makes the Merkel-Macron deal a potential game changer is not the sum of money or their apparent backing for grants over loans; it is the financial mechanism to which both Merkel and Macron are now publicly committed and must now deliver or suffer enormous loss of face.

The Merkel-Macron proposal involves three crucial innovation­s, which may sound tediously technical but will vastly increase the flexibilit­y of EU fiscal policy and could ultimately transform European politics in a way that really proves comparable to the Hamilton-Jefferson deal.

The key innovation is financing the recovery fund with bonds issued directly by the EU in its own name and guaranteed by its own revenues, instead of using funds raised by national government­s, whether acting together or separately. Merkel presumably insisted on this mechanism to avoid the vexations of jointly guaranteed “Eurobonds,” which German public opinion deems politicall­y toxic and possibly unconstitu­tional, because German taxes could end up paying for Italian or Spanish debts.

But by relying on the EU, instead of national government­s, to issue bonds, the Merkel-Macron plan implies a second, more controvers­ial, innovation, which is clearly necessary to create a fiscal federation, but which European politician­s have always tried to avoid.

To guarantee and service hundreds of billions of euros of new borrowing on its own account, the EU will require more tax revenue than it now receives. Merkel and Macron have therefore proposed increasing the European Commission’s budget from 1.2% to 2% of EU gross national income, yielding about €180 billion per year in extra revenue.

To raise this amount, the EU will need to levy new taxes on its own account, in addition to the customs duties and small share of national VAT revenues which already flow automatica­lly to Brussels. The exact nature of the EU’s new taxes will presumably be the subject of fierce debate and fiercer lobbying.

But a broad consensus seems to be emerging that pan-European taxes should be based on economic activities that transcend national boundaries, such as carbon dioxide emissions, financial transactio­ns, and digital transactio­ns. Some of this extra tax revenue will flow into recovery projects, but most will be needed for other EU spending, such as the “cohesion funds,” which subsidize the poorer eastern countries (and help to buy off government­s that might otherwise block the recovery fund and other EU initiative­s and reforms) – and also to replace the United Kingdom’s net contributi­ons of roughly €10 billion per year.

The proposed sum for the recovery fund proposed by French President Emmanuel Macron and German Chancellor Angela Merkel is small change in an era when politician­s and central bankers conjure up trillions almost daily. But, if adopted, the proposal might be remembered as the moment when Europe became a genuine political federation.

That leads to the third game-changing innovation in the Merkel-Macron plan: permitting the EU to leverage its activities with borrowing, instead of just using the EU budget as a pass-through mechanism from pan-European taxes to current spending. Because of today’s near-zero interest rates for triple-A sovereign borrowers, the leverage potentiall­y available to the EU from a modest amount of extra revenue is enormous.

If the EU issued ten-year bonds, it would probably pay interest of zero or below, potentiall­y allowing almost unlimited borrowing, albeit with sinking funds to redeem the debts at maturity. But even a 50year bond could probably be issued with a coupon no higher than the 0.5% yield on Austria’s 50-year bond.

Better still, the EU could issue perpetual bonds with no redemption date, similar to the now-retired British and US “consols,” as proposed by the Spanish government and George Soros. This would allow the EU to borrow €500 billion at an interest cost of just €2.5 billion per year.

To put it another way, if the EU borrows €500 billion this year for a European recovery fund, then it could easily borrow another €1 trillion next year for a digital inclusion fund, and then maybe €2 trillion for a vehicle electrific­ation fund or €3 trillion for a comprehens­ive climatecha­nge fund. Such simple calculatio­ns show why European economic and political conditions could be completely transforme­d by the Merkel-Macron plan’s financial innovation­s.

There are big obstacles in achieving the unanimity the plan requires. The Frugal Four will vehemently object to offering grants, rather than loans, to the bloc’s Mediterran­ean members. But it is hard to imagine that any of these government­s will try to sabotage completely an initiative that equally “frugal” Germans support. Instead, the debate in Europe will probably accept the three technical principles just outlined, but focus instead on two separate controvers­ies: the amount of new EU borrowing and whether EU support should take the form of loans or outright grants.

On these two issues, a compromise acceptable to both sides should not be difficult to forge. The size of the recovery fund could be increased to something near the €1 trillion recommende­d by the European Commission without imposing any strain on the EU budget. But in exchange, the Frugals could insist on offering 50% of the support through loans instead of grants.

A compromise like this would make the Merkel-Macron plan even stronger. Loans with near-zero interest rates and long maturities are economical­ly almost equivalent to grants. And using loans instead of grants would make EU debt financiall­y more sustainabl­e, thereby maximizing the scope for further borrowing without risking the bloc’s tripleA rating.

The scope for such compromise­s suggests the EU could readily agree on a powerful recovery plan that preserves all three essential elements of the MerkelMacr­on proposal: bonds issued by the EU in its own name; pan-European taxes on cross-border activities; and leverage to benefit from low interest rates. If EU leaders can rise to this challenge, Europe’s “Hamiltonia­n moment” will finally have arrived.

 ??  ?? Anatole Kaletsky
Anatole Kaletsky
 ??  ?? From left: German Chancellor Angela Merkel shaking hands with French President Emmanuel Macron
From left: German Chancellor Angela Merkel shaking hands with French President Emmanuel Macron

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria