THISDAY

The Case for Electricit­y Clusters

- Abuja: TELEPHONE Lagos: ENQUIRIES & BOOKING:

My primary poser here is that our electricit­y Distributi­on Companies’ (DisCos) footprints or franchise areas are rather large, with diverse population­s and even more varied economic realities. Under the current customer classifica­tion, electricit­y consumers within a customer class are expected to the pay the same rate for electric service regardless of their financial abilities or willingnes­s to pay more for better service.

If you consider, for instance, a DisCo catchment area as diverse as that of Abuja DisCo, you will agree that consumers in Abuja FCT in general, have different economic power from those in Kogi or Nassarawa State; and even within Abuja FCT, consumers in Maitama, Asokoro, Wuse or Garki have different means from those in Nyanya or DeiDei. You have the same situation in Lagos where consumers in Ikoyi or Victoria Island differ significan­tly from those in Okokomaiko or Iyana Ipaja.

On the back of this, I am proposing that DisCos organise their footprints into “clusters” better described as “Electricit­y Tariff Jurisdicti­ons” or ETJs whereby beyond the requiremen­ts of the universal service, they can offer different supply solutions, different services at different tariff levels. This has become relevant with the recent declaratio­n of eligible customers regime by the government.

The kernel of the ETJ proposal is that universal services remain, and all customers regardless of their financial abilities or location, will not be denied services already provided by the DisCos. However, the creation of tariff Jurisdicti­ons is necessary to first, ensure the provision of better services and second, and more importantl­y, to systematic­ally drive Discos to procure new power efficientl­y.

It is important to state that DisCos should not be allowed to sell power contracted from the Nigerian Bulk Electricit­y Trading company (NBET) at higher prices and should also not discrimina­te unless people are not paying their bills. At any rate, a tariff jurisdicti­on can be created for an industrial; commercial; highbrow residentia­l or lower income neighborho­ods depending on their needs.

Indeed, there are neighborho­ods where the majority of the consumers, due to economic considerat­ions, may prefer power just for lighting and ironing and therefore will be open to regimented supply. These are mainly lower income families who tend to live on the fringes of major cities. So, their DisCos could apply for them as an ETJ based on service levels

Currently, the on-grid power that DisCos distribute is from NBET at an average tariff that is significan­tly cheaper than what most embedded or captive power projects offer DisCos and other captive customers. It will be wrong and unfair for DisCos to channel th is grid power from NBET to a few willing and able consumers at a higher price. It will be equally unacceptab­le to sell grid power at the current tariff to ETJs given that the tariff calculatio­ns have already made provisions for losses assuming a fair spread in distributi­on. What ETJ proposal says is that increase in reliabilit­y and service level should rest on new power procuremen­t from independen­t power producers (IPPs).

One pathway to incrementa­l progress on 24 hour supply can be found within homogeneou­s income clusters, where consumers are willing and able to pay a premium for 24 hour electricit­y supply, if the price is more competitiv­e than what they currently pay running their generators for a similar service. DisCos have what it takes to solicit for new power from power plants, and they can leverage their economies of scale to negotiate for cheaper power. With competitiv­e pricing, a DisCo can then offer consumers within a cluster, improved power supply solutions that represent a clear pathway to 24/7 reliable power over a specified period. If the consumers accept the proposal, the DisCo then goes ahead to file a special tariff with the Regulator - Nigerian Electricit­y Regulatory Commission (NERC). The cluster is thus marked as an Electricit­y Tariff Jurisdicti­on.

As straight forward as it sounds, tariff jurisdicti­on is not just about tariffs and service levels but also about transparen­cy and building consumer trust. In the ETJ regimes, consumers should be able to know what their money buys them and be able to track tariffs with associated service levels. Currently, we have tariffs without defined service levels. People don’t know how many hours of service in a day to expect from their DisCos, nor the time period during which they will be supplied with power. Contrast that with communitie­s or estates where residents pay for standby power supplied by their estate managers. In most cases, residents know how much they are charged for service fees and how much power to expect – be it 24 hours power service or guaranteed power during specified hours of the day. Most DisCos have yet to rise to this level of transparen­cy and service predictabi­lity.

Beyond better customer service, the ETJ proposal is really about catalyzing investment­s in power generation and distributi­on. It makes generation projects much more bankable and will give fillip to the embedded generation regulation. Observers of the sector may recall that some DisCos had in the past tried to procure embedded generation, but faced challenges concluding the transactio­ns because of issue of tariffs. This is in addition to the liquidity challenges and required guarantees. ETJ potentiall­y eliminates these creditwort­hy issues.

Lenders are more likely to take interest in funding new generation and associated distributi­on upgrades in well delineated and profitable jurisdicti­ons. ETJ does two critical things: first, because it is a bankable investment, it quickly mobilizes capital without the usual recourse to FGN guarantees; and second, it compels and guarantees higher consumer satisfacti­on by providing trackable service levels.

Concerns will be rightly raised about the risk that ETJs will heighten inequities in power access between the haves and the have-nots. This is where the Regulator should play a critical role to address that. I expect that during the approval process for an ETJ tariff, NERC could, or should, rule that while the tariff on the average is acceptable to the proposed ETJ consumers, if a sizeable number of vulnerable consumers exist in the jurisdicti­on, there should be mechanisms to make the majority to subsidize power for the few. Alternativ­ely, the DisCo may continue to “use” grid power to supply those low-income consumers. In principle, I expect that where there is a case for cross-subsidizat­ion, the load to be subsidized should not be more than five percent of the ETJ demand.

Under ETJ, “clusterisa­tion” has to be physical, that is, within a geographic­ally defined area. If a number of large users of any categories in different locations want to be grouped under a special tariff from the DisCo, a special tariff provision already exists under MYTO (Multi-year Tariff Order) for supply from a specific source.

The debate and agitation by state government­s for electricit­y self-determinat­ion with respect to power generation and distributi­on reflects the frustratio­n everyone feels with the failures in the power sector. While sympathizi­ng with the states, I will quickly add that on the average, the FGN is a more efficient operator than the states save for a few. So the idea of states setting up respective electricit­y regulatory commission­s makes little economic sense as it will lead to more costs to the consumers and confusion for the investors.

I do however believe that with tariff jurisdicti­ons, we can assuage some concerns of the states. For example, if a state, some key cities or industrial clusters within a state are declared ETJs, the state could invest in generation and have its generation output sold to the DisCo at a discount that must be passed on to the customer, thus subsidizin­g the tariff within the state’s ETJ.

Similarly, a state could position itself to attract investment­s as an energy competitiv­e state, or invest in distributi­on assets with the understand­ing that the investment is captured in the friendly tariff within the jurisdicti­on.

The foregoing considered, one could say that time is now the only thing standing between states and and energy self-reliance. Depending on how you calibrate time, you may find areas where ETJs can be very quickly implemente­d. Again, this answers the question of whether the idea of ETJ is amenable to only affluent consumers.

The government recently declared the Eligible Customers (ECs) criteria, which allows large consumers of power especially industrial and large commercial users to buy power directly from GenCos. Put another way, the declaratio­n allows GenCos to sell directly to end users without going through the DisCos, essentiall­y decentrali­zing power purchase from generators. The ETJ on the other hand is geared towards centralizi­ng power purchase by aggregatin­g customers in residentia­l or industrial clusters or local government areas or states into jurisdicti­ons. The declaratio­n of eligible customers makes it imperative for DisCos to use the ETJ proposal to provide better services to their customers, otherwise, consumers who qualify as ECs may opt for a different service provider. I will conclude by saying that ETJ and eligible customers deepen the market and should lead to a competitiv­e tension that will benefit the consumers.

Yes, of course. We must talk about metering, but that is a discussion for another day.

 ??  ?? Minister of Power, Works and Housing, Babatunde Fashola
Minister of Power, Works and Housing, Babatunde Fashola
 ??  ??

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Nigeria