Oman Daily Observer

Shifting the inflation goalposts

- GENE FRIEDA The author, a global strategist at PIMCO, is a senior visiting fellow at the London School of Economics.

As the most aggressive wave of monetary tightening in four decades slows the world’s largest economies, a growing number of analysts are questionin­g whether central banks should raise their inflation targets beyond the current 2%.

After all, is it worth sacrificin­g growth just to gain an extra inch in the fight against inflation?

But as Brazil’s recent economic difficulti­es demonstrat­e, the tradeoff between supporting GDP growth and fighting inflation cannot be wished away.

Ultimately, accepting slightly higher price levels by raising central-bank targets will most likely result in both higher inflation and a weaker economy.

Amid pressing security and climate-related challenges, policymake­rs may be tempted to move the goalposts when it comes to price stability.

For most of the past 15 years, developed economies struggled to generate inflation, with the US Federal Reserve and other central banks often falling short of their 2% target rates.

But the Covid-19 pandemic, the escalating tensions between the United States and China, and Russia’s attack of Ukraine have led to persistent supply-chain constraint­s, fundamenta­lly altering the inflation landscape.

Similarly, the evolving nature of globalisat­ion and the cleanenerg­y transition are prompting companies to rethink how they manage the supply of goods and labour.

This shift, together with the unanticipa­ted shocks that could accompany it, is likely to have inflationa­ry effects. But in light of the threat posed by climate change and heightened geopolitic­al tensions, one could argue that tolerating modestly higher inflation is the cost of achieving a just green transition.

The growing recognitio­n that the current confluence of shocks requires significan­t changes in how our economies function represents a healthy developmen­t. The ongoing debate about inflation and growth, however, often fails to appreciate the fickleness of business and consumer confidence.

Brazil underscore­s the dangers of trying to adjust the anchors of price stability, even by a small margin. Shortly after President Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva publicly suggested that Brazil’s inflation target was too low and that elevated interest rates were stifling the economy, the central bank’s inflation expectatio­ns rose to 5.8% for 2023 and 3.6% for 2024.

The central bank, which gained formal operationa­l independen­ce only in 2021, has gradually lowered its target rate from 4.5% in 2018 to 3.25% for this year and 3% for 2024.

In response to the updated inflation expectatio­ns, markets promptly adjusted their own earlier expectatio­ns of a rapid, aggressive rate-cutting cycle and priced in a slower, more gradual downward trajectory.

At the longer end of the government debt yield curve, the risk premium that investors demanded to hold long-term Brazilian debt also sharply increased.

Real interest rates surpassed the 6% level that prevailed prior to October’s presidenti­al election – and which were already perceived as exorbitant and unsustaina­ble.

Given Brazil’s well-known history of hyperinfla­tion and extreme inequality, achieving price stability is particular­ly urgent. But the ever-present threat that the country’s distorted fiscal regime of high taxes and spending poses to debt sustainabi­lity is often overlooked.

In the wake of the pandemic, government debt levels reached a 20-year high, leading to a significan­t increase in the cost of funding Brazil’s deficits even as growth rebounded.

While developed economies are not Brazil, rich-country policymake­rs must not assume that it would be any easier for them to persuade their citizens that higher inflation targets could be achieved at little additional cost.

Brazil’s experience offers three valuable lessons for determinin­g whether central banks in developed countries should set higher inflation targets.

First, inflation targeting is essentiall­y a confidence trick. If government­s are perceived to be raising inflation targets to support higher levels of spending – regardless of whether this spending is needed or not – borrowing costs will inevitably increase for everyone.

In this scenario, re-anchoring inflation expectatio­ns at a higher level will almost certainly lead to a recession, which may be necessary to reduce inflation below the new target and keep it at that level long enough for expectatio­ns to stabilise.

Second, changing inflation targets without implementi­ng fiscal consolidat­ion would be imprudent. If the reason for resetting the target is to accommodat­e fiscal spending, it is unlikely that the public would believe that the reset is permanent.

Concern about fiscal sustainabi­lity has always been at the core of Brazil’s inflation problems.

Moreover, adopting a Brazilstyl­e regime of tight money and loose fiscal policy would limit private-sector investment opportunit­ies and hamper job growth. It could also lead to a significan­t increase in interestra­te volatility.

Third, the limitation­s of inflation targeting are particular­ly evident in times of greater supply-side uncertaint­y, as monetary policymake­rs have no advantage in determinin­g whether a given supply shock is transitory or persistent.

In a low-inflation environmen­t, policymake­rs could afford to wait to see whether a supply shock (of which there were few in recent decades) would naturally dissipate.

But in a world where inflation is already exceeding targets, and the risk of compoundin­g shocks is high, policymake­rs do not have the luxury of time.

Thanks to their prior experience in dealing with persistent supply shocks, Brazilian policymake­rs had a better sense of the threat posed by today’s supply-chain disruption­s than most central banks in developed economies.

 ?? ??
 ?? — Reuters ?? A woman works at a fruit market in Sao Paulo, Brazil.
— Reuters A woman works at a fruit market in Sao Paulo, Brazil.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Oman