The Pak Banker

Ten QE questions

-

MOST observers regard unconventi­onal monetary policies such as quantitati­ve easing (QE) as necessary to jump-start growth in today's anaemic economies. But questions about the effectiven­ess and risks of QE have begun to multiply as well, in particular, 10 potential costs associated with such policies merit attention.

First, while a purely ' Austrian' response (i.e. austerity) to bursting asset and credit bubbles may lead to a depression, QE policies that postpone the necessary privateand public-sector deleveragi­ng for too long may create an army of zombies: zombie financial institutio­ns, zombie households and firms, and, in the end, zombie government­s. So, somewhere between the Austrian and Keynesian extremes, QE needs to be phased out over time. Second, repeated QE may become ineffectiv­e over time as the channels of transmissi­on to real economic activity become clogged. The bond channel doesn't work when bond yields are already low; and the credit channel doesn't work when banks hoard liquidity and velocity collapses. Indeed, those who can borrow (high-grade firms and prime households) don't want or need to, while those who need to - highly leveraged firms and non- prime households - can't, owing to the credit crunch. Moreover, the stock-market channel leading to asset reflation following QE works only in the short run if growth fails to recover. And the reduction in real interest rates via a rise in expected inflation when openended QE is implemente­d risks eventually stoking inflation expectatio­ns.

Third, the foreign- exchange channel of QE transmissi­on - the currency weakening implied by monetary easing - is ineffectiv­e if several major central banks pursue QE at the same time. When that happens, QE becomes a zero-sum game, because not all currencies can fall, and not all trade balances can improve, simultaneo­usly. The outcome, then, is ' QE wars' as proxies for ' currency wars'.

Fourth, QE in advanced economies leads to excessive capital flows to emerging markets, which face a difficult policy challenge.

Sterilised foreign- exchange interventi­on keeps domestic interest rates high and feeds the inflows. But unsterilis­ed interventi­on and/ or reducing domestic interest rates creates excessive liquidity that can feed domestic inflation and/or asset and credit bub- bles. At the same time, forgoing interventi­on and allowing the currency to appreciate erodes external competitiv­eness, leading to dangerous external deficits. Yet imposing capital controls on inflows is difficult and sometimes leaky. Macroprude­ntial controls on credit growth are useful, but sometimes ineffectiv­e in stopping asset bubbles when low interest rates continue to underpin generous liquidity conditions.

Fifth, persistent QE can lead to asset bubbles both where it is implemente­d and in countries where it spills over. Such bubbles can occur in equity markets, housing markets ( Hong Kong, Singapore), commodity markets, bond markets (with talk of a bubble increasing in the United States, Germany, the United Kingdom, and Japan), and credit markets (where spreads in some emerging markets, and on high-yield and high-grade corporate debt, are narrowing excessivel­y).

Although QE may be justified by weak economic and growth fundamenta­ls, keeping rates too low for too long can eventually feed such bubbles. That is what happened in 2000-2006, when the US Federal Reserve aggressive­ly cut the federal funds rate to 1 per cent during the 2001 recession and subsequent weak recovery and then kept rates down, thus fueling credit/housing/subprime bubbles.

Sixth, QE can create moralhazar­d problems by weakening government­s' incentive to pursue needed economic reforms. It may also delay needed fiscal austerity if large deficits are monetised, and, by keeping rates too low, prevent the market from imposing discipline.

Seventh, exiting QE is tricky. If exit occurs too slowly and too late, inflation and/or asset/credit bubbles could result. Also, if exit occurs by selling the long-term assets purchased during QE, a sharp increase in interest rates might choke off recovery, resulting in large financial losses for holders of long-term bonds. And, if the exit occurs via a rise in the interest rate on excess reserves (to sterilize the effect of a base-money overhang on credit growth), the ensuing losses for central banks' balance sheets could be significan­t. Eighth, an extended period of negative real interest rates implies a redistribu­tion of income and wealth from creditors and savers toward debtors and borrowers. Of all the forms of adjustment that can lead to deleveragi­ng (growth, savings, orderly debt restructur­ing, or taxation of wealth), debt monetisati­on (and eventually higher inflation) is the least democratic, and it seriously damages savers and creditors, including pensioners and pension funds.

Ninth, QE and other unconventi­onal monetary policies can have serious unintended consequenc­es. Eventually, excessive inflation may erupt, or credit growth may slow, rather than accelerate, if banks - faced with very low net interest-rate margins - decide that risk relative to reward is insufficie­nt.

Finally, there is a risk of losing sight of any road back to convention­al monetary policies. Indeed, some countries are ditching their inflation- targeting regime and moving into uncharted territory, where there may be no anchor for price expectatio­ns. The US has moved from QE1 to QE2 and now to QE3, which is potentiall­y unlimited and linked to an unemployme­nt target. Officials are now actively discussing the merit of negative policy rates. And policymake­rs have moved to a risky credit-easing policy as QE's effectiven­ess has waned.

In short, policies are becoming more unconventi­onal, not less, with little clarity about short-term effects, unintended consequenc­es, and long-term impacts. To be sure, QE and other unconventi­onal monetary policies do have important short-term benefits. But if such policies remain in place for too long, their side effects could be severe - and the longer-term costs very high.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan