The Pak Banker

Binding the Fed won’t help the economy

- Frederic S. Mishkin

WHEN Federal Reserve Chair Janet Yellen delivered her semiannual testimony to Congress this month, lawmakers once again expressedc­oncern that the central bank was insufficie­ntly transparen­t and may be pursing an over-expansiona­ry monetary policy that could lead to high inflation. This was but the latest round of questions about the Fed's considerab­le discretion to take actions such as adjusting the federal funds rate without interferen­ce from Congress or the President. Late last year, a bill passed the House that would require the central bank to abide by a so-called policy-instrument rule and set its policy instrument based on certain available data, including inflation, gross domestic product and unemployme­nt. Would such a rule produce better economic outcomes? The answer is no, for four reasons:

First, for the constraint to be effective, policy makers must have a reliable model of the economy. For example, a successful policy-instrument rule would require the central bank to have confidence in the accuracy of the measure used to ensure that the unemployme­nt rate isn't contributi­ng to either increases or declines in inflation. Unfortunat­ely, research has shown that the metric most often used for the calculatio­n -- the non-accelerati­ng inflation rate of unemployme­nt, or NAIRU -- delivers highly uncertain results. Indeed, the instances of very high inflation in the U.S. in the 1970s were due to Fed policy makers' belief that the NAIRU was around 4 percent, when it actually was closer to 6 percent. Based on this faulty informatio­n, the Fed did not pursue contractio­nary monetary policy when the unemployme­nt rate fell below 6 percent, as it should have, leading to an upward spiral in inflation.

Second, a policy-instrument rule would remain valid only so long as the structure of the economy didn't undergo substantia­l changes. The failure of past monetary targeting in many countries demonstrat­ed the dangers. In 1980, the Swiss National Bank set a growth rate target for a narrow monetary aggregate. When the country introduced a new interbank payment system in 1988, this structural change caused a severe drop in banks' desired holdings of this narrow money because a smaller amount was now needed relative to overall spending in the economy. Adherence to the policy rule, however, caused the Swiss inflation rate to rise above 5 percent in 1990 and 1991, well above the prevailing levels in the rest of Western Europe.

Third, a policy-instrument rule can be too rigid because it cannot foresee every contingenc­y. This was made clear in the recent financial crisis: Almost no one could have predicted that problems in one small part of the system -- subprime mortgage lending -would lead to the worst meltdown since the Great Depression. The unpreceden­ted monetary policy that the Fed undertook to prevent the crisis from escalating, perhaps even leading to a depression, could not have been written into a policy rule ahead of time. For example, the Fed cut the federal funds rate starting in the third quarter of 2007, when any reasonable policy rule would have argued against this course of action -- that is, when inflation was rising and real GDP growth was strong. Indeed, in hindsight, the Fed should have pursued more expansiona­ry monetary policy even earlier: The recession would then have been less severe and inflation would have stayed closer to 2 percent, the central bank's current objective for theinflati­on rate.

Fourth, a policy-instrument rule does not easily incorporat­e the need to use judgment. Monetary policy is as much art as science. Central bankers need to look at a wide range of informatio­n to decide on the best course, and some of this informatio­n is not easily quantifiab­le, making judgment a critical element of success. Yet even though a policy-instrument rule won't ensure the best results, that doesn't mean that central banks should have complete discretion, which can be undiscipli­ned, non-transparen­t and lead to poor economic outcomes. One way that central banks have constraine­d discretion is by adopting a numerical target for the inflation rate. Although it acted later than others, the Fed finally set a 2 percent inflation objective in January 2012.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan