The Pak Banker

Free markets improved more lives than anything ever

- Noah Smith -BLOOMBERG

Harvard economist Dani Rodrik has a long and thoughtful essay about the shortcomin­gs of neoliberal­ism -- the economic program of free markets and free trade. He writes: Economists' contributi­ons to public debate are often biased in one direction, in favor of more trade, more finance, and less government. That is why economists have developed a reputation as cheerleade­rs for neoliberal­ism, even if mainstream economics is very far from a paean to laissez-faire. The economists who let their enthusiasm for free markets run wild are in fact not being true to their own discipline.

As someone who has done decades of pioneering work in the field of trade and growth, and who has been intimately involved in practical policy-making, Rodrik is as much of an expert on this topic as anyone . But although his criticisms are accurate, he overlooks much of the good that neoliberal­ism has done.

Rodrik very wisely explains why it's so easy for economists to seem like shills for simplistic free-market policies. Confronted with a desire for quick fixes and easy explanatio­ns, many economists instinctiv­ely revert back to the toy models they learned in their introducto­ry economics courses -- models where freemarket competitio­n solves almost any problem. As Rodrik notes, these models represent a common fable -- University of Connecticu­t law professor James Kwak calls it "economism" -that ignores a million and one important features of real-world markets. Government insti- tutions, for example, matter a lot -- from the corporatis­m of 20th century Japan to Germany's innovative unions, there are many flavors of capitalism that all seem to work fairly well. And without good institutio­ns, capitalism can easily degenerate into inefficien­t monopoly, crash-prone financial excess, short- sighted environmen­tal destructio­n, or a number of other undesirabl­e conditions.

But when it comes to the harms that neoliberal­ism has wrought, Rodrik cherry-picks quite a bit. He focuses on two countries -- Mexico and Chile. In the 1970s and 1980s, under dictator Augusto Pinochet, Chile took advice from a number of free-market economists, but the results were underwhelm­ing. Since undertakin­g its own free-market reforms and signing the North American Free Trade Agreement, Mexico's economy has underperfo­rmed more interventi­onist countries like South Korea and China.

These examples of neoliberal disappoint­ment are real enough. It's no accident that both come from Latin America -- the region where neoliberal advice, in the form of a 10-point plan called the Washington Consensus, garnered the most publicity. The Washington Consensus has been the target of bitter criticism for years, and Rodrik himself has been one of its most prominent detractors.

But Latin America is only one part of the world. Elsewhere, broadly neoliberal ideas have been much more of a success. Rodrik's essay should have taken these into considerat­ion.

Take China. In the 1980s, after decades of economic and social disaster under Mao Zedong, China started experiment­ing with a market economy under party leader Deng Xiaoping. The regime began to allow small businesses and granted limited land rights. State-owned enterprise­s were partially privatized. The country opened to foreign investment, and went from a state of isolation to the world's biggest trading economy. By 2005, China's market economy passed its state-run economy in size. What happened after China's market reforms is now wellknown -- the most dramatic explosion of economic growth in world history.

As Rodrik points out, state interventi­on still plays a prominent role in China's economy. But the shift from a rigid command-and-control economy to one that blended state and market approaches -- and the liberaliza­tion of trade -was undoubtedl­y a neoliberal reform. Though Deng's changes were mostly done in an ad-hoc, common sense manner, he did invite famed neoliberal economist Milton Friedman to give him advice. A decade after China began its experiment, India followed suit. In 1991, after a sharp recession, Prime Minister Narasimha Rao and Finance Minister Manmohan Singh scrapped a cumbersome system of business licensing, eased curbs on foreign investment, ended many state-sanctioned monopolies, lowered tariffs and did a bunch of other neoliberal things. Although the results were not as dramatic as in China, there was a sustained rise in economic growth:

It's almost impossible to overstate how important the growth explosions of India and China have been. So many people live in these two supergiant countries -- almost 40 percent of humanity, several times the total living in the developed world -- that together they determine the entire shape of human progress. Though the free-market approach unquestion­ably has its shortcomin­gs, it would be wrong to label it "bad economics," as Rodrik does. The truth, as usual, is more complicate­d.

 ??  ?? As someone who has done decades of pioneering work in the field of trade and growth, and who has been intimately involved in practical policy-making, Rodrik is as much of an expert on this topic as anyone . But although his criticisms are accurate, he...
As someone who has done decades of pioneering work in the field of trade and growth, and who has been intimately involved in practical policy-making, Rodrik is as much of an expert on this topic as anyone . But although his criticisms are accurate, he...

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan