The Pak Banker

Has austerity been vindicated?

- Robert Skidelsky

Harvard University Professor Alberto Alesina has returned to the debate on budget deficits, austerity, and growth. Back in 2010, Alesina told European finance ministers that "many even sharp reductions of budget deficits have been accompanie­d and immediatel­y followed by sustained growth rather than recessions even in the very short run" (my italics). Now, with fellow economists Carlo Favero and Francesco Giavazzi, Alesina has written a new book titled Austerity: When It Works and When It Doesn't, which recently received a favorable review from his Harvard colleague Kenneth Rogoff.

New book, old tune. The authors' conclusion, in a nutshell, is that "in certain cases the direct output cost of spending cuts is more than compensate­d for by increases in other components of aggregate demand." The implicatio­n is that austerity - cutting the budget deficit, not expanding it - may well be the right policy in a recession.

Alesina's previous work in this area with Silvia Ardagna was criticized by the Internatio­nal Monetary Fund and other economists for its faulty econometri­cs and exaggerate­d conclusion­s. And this new book, which analyzes 200 multi-year austerity plans carried out in 16 countries in the Organizati­on for Economic Cooperatio­n and Developmen­t (OECD) between 1976 and 2014, will also no doubt keep the number crunchers busy.

But that is not the main point. Correlatio­n is not causation. The associatio­n of fiscal

retrenchme­nt and economic growth tells us nothing about the underlying relationsh­ip between the two. Does shrinking the deficit cause economic growth, or does growth cause the deficit to shrink? All the econometri­cs in the world cannot prove that one caused the other, or that both may not be the result of something else. There are simply too many omitted variables - that is, other possible causes of either or both outcomes. So-called statistica­l proofs always start with a theory of causation, to which the data are "fitted" to get the result the theorist wants.

Alesina's theory rests on two conceptual pillars. The main one is that if deficits persist, businesses and consumers will expect higher taxes and will therefore invest and consume less. Spending cuts, on the other hand, signal lower taxes in the future, and thus stimulate investment and consumptio­n.

The second, supplement­ary pillar is the assumption that rising public debt leads investors to expect a default. This expectatio­n forces up interest rates on government bonds, leading to higher overall borrowing costs. Austerity, by stopping the growth of debt, can bring about a "sizable reduction" in interest rates, and thus enable increased investment.

This supplement­ary case cannot be regarded as a general rule. If a country has its own central bank and issues its own currency, the government can cause interest rates to be whatever it wants them to be by ordering the central bank to print money. In this case, low interest rates will be the result not of austerity, but rather of monetary expansion. And this, of course, is what has happened with quantitati­ve easing in the United States, the United Kingdom and the eurozone. Interest rates have stayed at rock bottom for years as central banks have pumped hundreds of billions of dollars, pounds and euros into their economies.

So we are left with Alesina's main pillar: a credible commitment to public spending cuts today will boost output by removing the expectatio­n of higher taxes tomorrow. The same argument explains why, on Alesina's view, it is better to reduce the deficit by cutting spending than by raising taxes. Spending cuts address the "problem" of "the automatic growth of [welfare] entitlemen­ts and other spending programs," whereas tax increases do not.

Alesina writes: "Modern macroecono­mics emphasizes that people's decisions about what to do today are influenced by their expectatio­ns of what will happen in the future." John Maynard Keynes, too, understood the crucial importance of expectatio­ns: He is credited by John Hicks with introducin­g the "method of expectatio­ns" into economics. However, Keynes' expectatio­nal map was very different from Alesina's. His investors do not form their expectatio­ns by looking at the government's deficit and calculatin­g what effect it will have on their future tax bills. In fact, they scarcely notice the deficit at all.

What they do notice is the size of their markets. For Keynes, entreprene­urs' decisions to create jobs depend on their expected income from increasing employment. An economic downturn reduces their expected sales proceeds, causing them to lay off workers. A cut in government spending implies that they can expect still fewer sales, causing them to lay off even more workers, thus deepening the recession.

 ??  ?? The authors' conclusion, in a nutshell, is that "in certain cases the direct output cost of spending cuts is
more than compensate­d for by increases in other components of aggregate demand." The implicatio­n is that austerity - cutting the budget deficit, not expanding it - may well be the right policy in a recession.
The authors' conclusion, in a nutshell, is that "in certain cases the direct output cost of spending cuts is more than compensate­d for by increases in other components of aggregate demand." The implicatio­n is that austerity - cutting the budget deficit, not expanding it - may well be the right policy in a recession.

Newspapers in English

Newspapers from Pakistan